economics problem solving example

Live revision! Join us for our free exam revision livestreams Watch now →

Reference Library

Collections

  • See what's new
  • All Resources
  • Student Resources
  • Assessment Resources
  • Teaching Resources
  • CPD Courses
  • Livestreams

Study notes, videos, interactive activities and more!

Economics news, insights and enrichment

Currated collections of free resources

Browse resources by topic

  • All Economics Resources

Resource Selections

Currated lists of resources

  • Study Notes

What is the fundamental economic problem?

Last updated 13 Jul 2023

  • Share on Facebook
  • Share on Twitter
  • Share by Email

The basic economic problem, also known as the fundamental economic problem, refers to the scarcity of resources in relation to the unlimited wants and needs of individuals and societies. It is the central issue in economics and arises due to the imbalance between what people desire and the resources available to fulfill those desires.

In essence, the basic economic problem can be summarized by three key questions:

  • What to produce: Since resources are limited, societies must decide what goods and services to produce and in what quantities. This involves making choices about which products or services are most needed or desired by the population.
  • How to produce: Once the decision on what to produce is made, societies must determine the most efficient and effective methods of production. This involves deciding on the combination of resources to use, such as labor, capital, and technology, to produce the desired goods and services.
  • For whom to produce: After determining what and how to produce, societies need to allocate the produced goods and services to different individuals and groups. This raises questions about the distribution of resources and the equitable allocation of goods and services among the population.

The basic economic problem arises from the reality of scarcity. Resources such as land, labor, capital, and natural resources are limited, while human wants and needs are virtually unlimited. As a result, individuals, businesses, and societies must make choices and trade-offs to allocate resources efficiently, optimize production, and satisfy the most pressing needs and desires.

Economics as a social science discipline seeks to study and analyse the basic economic problem and develop theories and models to understand how societies make decisions regarding resource allocation, production, and distribution in the face of scarcity.

Here are some of the ways that economic systems try to address the fundamental economic problem:

  • Market economies: Market economies are based on the principle of supply and demand. Prices are determined by the interaction of buyers and sellers in the market. This system allows for the efficient allocation of resources, but it can also lead to inequality and environmental problems.
  • Planned (command) economies: Planned economies are based on the principle of central planning. The government decides what goods and services will be produced and how resources will be allocated. This system can ensure that everyone's basic needs are met, but it can also be inefficient and inflexible.
  • Mixed economies: Mixed economies combine elements of market economies and planned economies. The government plays a role in the economy, but it also allows for some degree of free market activity. This system is often seen as a way to balance the efficiency of market economies with the equity of planned economies.

The fundamental economic problem is a complex issue that has no easy solutions. However, different economic systems offer different approaches to addressing the problem.

  • Water Scarcity
  • Scarcity bias
  • Resource Scarcity
  • Opportunity cost

You might also like

Venezuela – fingerprinting as a rationing device..

26th August 2014

economics problem solving example

Opportunity Cost - Some Numerical Examples as a Worksheet

11th August 2015

economics problem solving example

The Opportunity Cost of a pair of Apple AirPods

12th September 2016

Behavioural Economics (Quizlet Revision Activity)

Quizzes & Activities

Basic Economic Problem - Revision Video Playlist

Topic Videos

Opportunity Cost - Two Applied Examples

Price mechanism in action - californian drought raises grocery prices.

11th October 2022

economics problem solving example

Who should pay to clean up the UK's rivers?

2nd October 2023

Our subjects

  • › Criminology
  • › Economics
  • › Geography
  • › Health & Social Care
  • › Psychology
  • › Sociology
  • › Teaching & learning resources
  • › Student revision workshops
  • › Online student courses
  • › CPD for teachers
  • › Livestreams
  • › Teaching jobs

Boston House, 214 High Street, Boston Spa, West Yorkshire, LS23 6AD Tel: 01937 848885

  • › Contact us
  • › Terms of use
  • › Privacy & cookies

© 2002-2024 Tutor2u Limited. Company Reg no: 04489574. VAT reg no 816865400.

Browse Course Material

Course info.

  • Prof. Jonathan Gruber

Departments

As taught in.

  • Microeconomics

Learning Resource Types

Principles of microeconomics, problem set 7.

« Previous | Next »

Preparation

The problem set is comprised of challenging questions that test your understanding of the material covered in the course. Make sure you have mastered the concepts and problem solving techniques from the following sessions before attempting the problem set:

  • Monopoly II
  • Oligopoly I

Problem Set and Solutions

  • Problem Set Questions (PDF)
  • Problem Set Solutions (PDF)

Problem Solving Video

In the video below, a teaching assistant demonstrates his approach to the solution for problem 2a-e from the problem set. The teaching assistant notes common mistakes made by students and provides problem solving techniques for approaching similar questions on the problem set and exams.

  • Download video
  • Download transcript

facebook

You are leaving MIT OpenCourseWare

Logo for Florida State College at Jacksonville Pressbooks

Want to create or adapt books like this? Learn more about how Pressbooks supports open publishing practices.

3 Economic Models and Problems

Economic models.

In studying economics, we must  build models  and  test theories  . The purpose of economic models is to  understand  the complex reality and  predict  outcomes.

Because the world we live in is too complex to be studied as it is, we need to build models to reduce such complexity. Models are simplified versions of the complex reality built to answer only certain questions. A good model is one based on certain assumptions (which are often false statements, when compared to their applicability in the real world) that is able to predict well most of the time. Models are constantly refined, and some of their assumptions relaxed, so as to build better models (with better predictability). Theories need to be tested with real-world data. Empirical research tests such models and their hypotheses. Theoretical research builds such models in an effort to explain certain aspects of the complex economic reality.

Economic Assumptions

Ceteris Paribus — “Other Things Being Equal” — is the biggest assumption in Economics. In order to establish a relationship between two variables, you must hold all other variables constant.

Economic Relationships

Economic relationships can often be expressed as mathematical functions. Variable Y is a function of variable X; when X changes, Y responds either by increasing or decreasing. Mathematically, economic relationships can be captured by linear or non-linear functions.  (4)

Linear Functions:

Y = 20 + 4X

D = 100 − 2P

S = 35 + 4P

Non-linear Functions:

Y = A × K  1/3  L  2/3

Y = a + b × e  x

The Economic Way of Thinking

People make choices. Every choice involves a tradeoff, which represents an exchange — giving up one thing to get something else. In addition, people make rational choices by comparing the costs and the benefits of their alternative options, as well as using all of the available information to them up to that point in time. In other words, a rational choice is made when one uses all the available resources to most effectively satisfy the wants of the person making the choice.

The benefit of a given alternative option is the gain or pleasure it brings and is determined by personal preferences — by what a person likes and dislikes and the intensity of those feelings. Economists measure the benefit of something by what a person is willing to give up to get it.

The cost of a given alternative option is what must be given up to get it. The  opportunity cost  of an option in Economics refers to the monetary value of the best alternative one must give up to obtain it. In a broader sense, the opportunity cost includes both direct and indirect costs associated with a given option. Only economists account for these indirect costs, such as the monetary value of the best alternative one must give up to obtain it. Accountants, for example, only consider the direct costs of a given option, the ones that require a direct outlay of money. Economists, on the other hand, consider a broader perspective by accounting for what we give up or sacrifice, which might not be readily observable.

The opportunity cost of attending college includes both direct costs of tuition and textbooks, and the indirect costs of a full-time or part-time job that the student could have had, but decided to give up in order to attend college full time. In summary, the opportunity cost of a given option is the best thing/alternative (usually measured as the monetary value) one  gives up  (sacrifices) to obtain that option.

Choices people make respond to  incentives  . An  incentive  is a reward that encourages an action, or a penalty that discourages an action. Changes in benefits and costs alter the incentives that we face when making choices. When incentives change, people’s decisions change. For example, if a research project assignment is weighed more heavily in the final grade calculation as a required assignment, as opposed to an optional assignment, the benefit of completing this required assignment increases for every student, and we would expect more students to complete this assignment, as they respond to this incentive.  (1)

Economic Problems

Throughout the course, we will elaborate on most of the following topics, representing major economic themes and macroeconomic problems:

Globalization, Job Outsourcing and Multinational Corporations, and the Information Age

Recent decades have seen a trend toward  globalization  , which is the expanding cultural, political, and economic connections among people around the world. One measure of this is the increased buying and selling of goods, services, and assets across national borders—in other words, international trade and financial capital flows.  (2)

On the other hand, globalization has caused many countries to experience  job outsourcing  and the  brain drain  phenomena.

Economics as a Policy Tool

Economics is a tool that helps us make an endless array of decisions.  Personal Economic Policy  involves decisions about an individual’s need for shelter, transportation, and time management.  Business Economic Policy  involves decisions made at the margin to accomplish a business’ goals such as increasing sales, opening a new branch, or gaining market share.  Government Economic Policy  is perhaps the most controversial of the three types of economic policies. How should goals such as better education, military preparedness, and safe food be balanced against limited tax revenue and the desire of individual members of government to be reelected?  (1)

Principles of Macroeconomics Copyright © by Lumen Learning is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License , except where otherwise noted.

Share This Book

  • Français

Egypt

  • No results found.
  • Preparatory

Lesson Explainer: Fundamental Economic Problem Economics • Third Year of Secondary School

In this explainer, we will learn how to recognize the fundamental economic problem.

The basic building blocks of economic activities are human needs and resources. Let us recall the definition and characteristics of human needs.

A need of an individual is a feeling of distress leading them to act to diminish or satisfy the need. While a need may be satisfied by consuming suitable resources, the quantity of an individual’s needs continues to increase over time. In the context of a society, we also know that human needs are widely varied between different individuals. In other words, there is a limitless and diverse demand for resources in a society.

We also recall that resources are categorized as free or scarce, in terms of their availability. The availability of free resources, such as air and water, far exceeds the demand for their consumption. If all resources were free, there would not be any economic problem in the society since they would be able to satisfy everyone’s needs.

However, we know that most resources are scarce, which means that needs for the resources far exceed their availability. Any economic problem can be traced back to the fundamental conflict between scarcity of resources and the limitless and diverse nature of human needs, which is known as the fundamental economic problem.

Definition: Fundamental Economic Problem

The fundamental economic problem states that human needs are diverse and continuously increasing, while resources to satisfy them are relatively limited.

We can represent the fundamental economic problem using the following diagram.

For instance, we can consider a need for transportation, which can be satisfied by purchasing a car. We know that a car is a scarce resource, which means that there is a greater number of people with this need compared to the number of available cars. Hence, some individuals will be able to obtain cars to satisfy their needs, while other individuals’ needs will not be satisfied. Furthermore, individuals with cars will likely develop new needs, for example, to obtain better cars, leading to an unending cycle of the fundamental economic problem that cannot be fully resolved.

Recall that a need for transportation is a secondary need, which is for achieving the happiness of the individual or improving the condition of the society. When we consider the fundamental economic problem involving this secondary need, its consequences do not seem grave. Let us consider this problem involving a primary need, which is essential for an individual’s survival.

The need to eat is a primary need, and every individual in a society has this need. The need to eat is also frequently renewed, and the satisfaction of the primary need to eat often motivates a new secondary need to eat better or more scarce food. Since these needs are limitless and diverse, there will not be enough food to satisfy every individual’s need. Because this need is tied to the individual’s survival, the scarcity of food creates a much more serious problem compared to the scarcity of cars. The survival of individuals is at stake when the fundamental economic problem is tied to primary needs.

In our first example, we will consider the root causes of the fundamental economic problem.

Example 1: The Fundamental Economic Problem

Which of the following are the two root causes of the fundamental economic problem?

  • Scarcity of resources
  • Maximizing profit
  • Social welfare
  • Unlimited human needs

In this example, we need to identify the root causes of the fundamental economic problem. Recall that the fundamental economic problem states the following: human needs are diverse and continuously increasing, while resources to satisfy them are limited.

The first part of the statement addresses the unlimited and diverse human needs, option IV, while the second part of the statement refers to the scarcity of resources, option I. Hence, the root causes of the fundamental economic problem are the scarcity of resources and unlimited human needs, which are I and IV.

In the previous problem, we identified the scarcity of resources and unlimited human needs as the root causes of the fundamental economic problem. Let us now consider how we, as individuals or as a society, can address the fundamental economic problem.

Definition: Economic Choices

Individuals or economic entities can address the fundamental economic problem by making economic choices. The objective of any economic choice is to allocate the limited resources to maximize their utility.

In the definition above, the term utility refers to the total satisfaction derived from the consumption of resources. Hence, when an economic entity , that is, an individual, a firm, or a government, makes economic choices, it considers how to maximize the benefits of the existing resources.

Making economic choices requires the entity to set priorities of different needs so that some will be satisfied before others. For instance, an individual can choose to satisfy the need to tour Italy, or a government can choose to fund the construction of a new school. These are examples of economic choices where an individual or a government decides to satisfy a specific need over others. Since making a choice inevitably means that we are not choosing the other options, we leave other needs unsatisfied when an economic choice is made.

Definition: Opportunity Cost

Opportunity costs are the effects or consequences of alternative options in an economic choice. If the effects are financial, which include profits and losses, the opportunity cost, or the cost of foregone options, can be written as a difference between the alternate and chosen options.

The relationship between the fundamental economic problem, economic choices, and opportunity costs are represented in the following diagram.

Opportunity costs are also known as missed opportunities. Let us consider possible opportunity costs of the economic choice to tour Italy. An example of nonfinancial opportunity costs may be the missed opportunity to visit relatives during that time. On the other hand, the cost of travel is a financial opportunity cost, which is measured in terms of the difference between the travel costs incurred by the tour and the savings that could be made by not undertaking the tour. Before making economic choices, the opportunity costs of all available options should be considered in order to maximize the benefit.

In the next example, we will examine the relationship between economic choices and opportunity costs.

Example 2: Economic Choices and Opportunity Costs

Which of the following correctly describes the relationship between opportunity costs and choices?

  • Opportunity cost refers to the financial implications of making choices.
  • If two individuals make the same economic choice, the opportunity cost for the two individuals is the same.
  • Every economic choice is accompanied by an opportunity cost.
  • Opportunity cost is always positive.
  • Opportunity cost is always negative.

In this example, we need to identify the correct statement regarding the relationship between opportunity costs and choices. Recall that choices are necessary because of the scarcity of resources and that the purpose of an economic choice is to allocate the limited resources to maximize benefits. We also recall that opportunity costs are the effects or consequences of alternative options in an economic choice.

Let us consider each option.

Option A: This option could be appealing since the word cost has a financial connotation. However, the opportunity cost does not have to be related to financial implications. Instead, it may represent the qualitative effects of foregone options. Hence, this statement is inaccurate.

Option B: Let us consider an example of opportunity cost in order to determine whether this statement is accurate. Say that two different individuals make the choice to tour Italy over summer. For one, the opportunity cost could be the missed opportunity to visit relatives, while for the other, the opportunity cost could be the missed opportunity to take courses over the summer to further their education. As this example demonstrates, opportunity costs of the same economic choices could vary between different individuals due to the different availability of alternative options. Hence, this statement is inaccurate.

Option C: Opportunity costs are inevitable in economic choices since there are always alternatives to consider. This is a true statement.

Options D and E: If the effects are financial, the opportunity cost is written as the difference between the alternate and chosen options. Since it is a difference, the opportunity cost may be positive or negative depending on which quantity is larger. Hence, this statement is inaccurate.

Option C is the only accurate description of opportunity costs and choices since every choice is accompanied by opportunity costs.

In the previous example, we considered the relationship between economic choices and opportunity costs. We learned that opportunity costs are widely varied depending on available alternative options. Opportunity costs for financial costs and benefits are often considered more objectively since they can be expressed explicitly as a difference. Qualitative opportunity costs should also be considered, although it is more difficult to remain objective regarding these items.

In the next example, we will identify different opportunity costs associated with a specific economic choice made by a national government.

Example 3: Understanding Opportunity Costs

After careful review, a national government decided to fund the construction of a bridge. Alternatives considered were the construction of a new high school and an increase in the wages of government employees. Which of the following is not an opportunity cost for the national government’s choice to fund the construction of the bridge?

  • Improved morale among government employees due to the raise in pay
  • Improvement in the quality of high school education
  • Improved efficiency in traffic due to the new bridge
  • Difference in financial cost between the construction of the bridge and the alternatives considered

The national government in this example decided to fund the construction of a bridge, where the alternative options considered were the construction of a new high school and an increase in the wages of government employees. We need to identify which of the given statements does not relate to opportunity costs. Recall that opportunity costs, also known as missed opportunities, are the effects or consequences of alternative options in an economic choice.

Option A: Improved morale among government employees is an effect we can expect from the alternative option of an increase in the wages of government employees. This can be considered as a possible missed opportunity; hence, it is an example of an opportunity cost associated with the current choice.

Option B: Improvement in the quality of high school education is an effect we can expect from the alternative option of the construction of a new high school. This can be considered as a possible missed opportunity; hence, it is an opportunity cost associated with the current choice.

Option C: Improved efficiency in traffic is an effect we can expect from the chosen option, which is the construction of a bridge. This is not an example of missed opportunities; hence, it is not an opportunity cost.

Option D: Recall that when opportunity costs are financial, they are expressed as the difference between the effects of the alternative and chosen options. Hence, the difference as mentioned here represents a financial opportunity cost associated with the current choice.

Option C, which describes the effect of the chosen option, is not an example of opportunity costs.

In the previous examples, we learned about opportunity costs resulting from economic choices. Let us now consider the efficiency of an economic system.

The efficiency of an economic system is measured by the amount of resources wasted during their allocation. An economic system is efficient if few to no resources are wasted. Since the goal of any economic choice is to allocate the limited resources to maximize benefits, good economic choices will lead to an efficient economic system. Other than considering the opportunity costs, what other factors affect the ability for governing entities to make good economic choices?

For a government to make good economic choices, it needs accurate and detailed information about the population it serves. Information can greatly aid economic decision making by reducing wasted resources during their allocation. In other words, the efficiency of an economic system is, for a large part, determined by the ability to obtain accurate and appropriate information when making economic choices. For instance, accurate data on the number of children in different regions of a nation will enable the government to choose the optimal location to build a new school and to satisfy the need for education. Accurate information about the state of poverty will enable the government to deliver available resources where the need is the greatest.

We can also consider the importance of information for individuals and companies. An individual with a need for shelter should have accurate information about available public shelters to efficiently satisfy the need. A company producing goods should have accurate information about how many consumers have the need for the goods it is producing. As we can see, the availability of accurate and appropriate information enables the reduction of wasted resources in economic choices made by individuals or companies.

Conversely, the problem of missing or inaccurate information is known as information failure.

Definition: Information Failure

Information failure is the deficiency in available information necessary for making economic choices.

Information failure often leads to bad economic choices, which lead to inefficient economic systems. For instance, inaccurate information about the number of children in different regions of a nation will likely cause the government to choose a site for a new school that is not optimal. This will produce wasted resources both from unnecessary transportation for children to get to school and some families deciding not to use the new school. This is an example of information failure in a government.

Information failure can occur for individuals as well. Incomplete information about harmful effects of certain ingredients may lead individuals to consume unhealthy food, which can worsen their health. This leads to wasted healthcare resources.

In the next example, we will identify an example of information failure.

Example 4: Understanding Information Failure

Which of the following is a description of information failure?

  • The government releases inaccurate unemployment numbers, causing the stock market to tumble.
  • A company produces an oversupply of toys due to data from an inaccurate survey.
  • An individual is undecided on which product to use due to too much available information from the Internet.
  • Reporting of unemployment numbers by the government is delayed, causing uncertainties in the stock market.

We recall that information failure is the deficiency in available information necessary for making efficient economic choices. Hence, we need to identify which of the given examples are poor economic choices resulting from deficiency in available information.

Let us consider each scenario.

Option A: In this scenario, the government produced an inaccurate report, which resulted in falling stock prices. While inaccurate information is involved in this scenario, falling stock prices is not an example of bad economic choices. Hence, this is not an example of information failure.

Option B: In this scenario, data from an inaccurate survey led a company to overproduce toys. Overproduction of toys is an example of an economic choice that resulted from the survey’s inaccurate information. This is an example of information failure.

Option C: In this scenario, too much information has left an individual undecided on a type of product to use. No economic choices have been made by the individual, and the problem is the oversupply of information rather than the deficiency of information. Hence, this is not an example of information failure.

Option D: In this scenario, the report of unemployment numbers is delayed, causing uncertainties in the stock market. The deficiency of information at this time has caused the problem, but there are no economic choices involved in this scenario. Hence, this is not an example of information failure.

Option B, which describes a company making a bad economic choice based on inaccurate information, is an example of information failure.

We have learned about the fundamental economic problem and its components as well as the effects of economic choices. When only a small number of needs and resources are involved in the fundamental economic problem, the optimal economic choices appear to be within reach. However, economic issues in today’s society are complex and multifaceted. The diversity of human needs and interconnected networks of different economic systems make economic issues very difficult and profound, but they also make this subject interesting and exciting.

Definition: Economics

Economics is a social science studying how individuals and societies use scarce resources to satisfy increasing and diverse needs.

In other words, economics seeks to solve the fundamental economic problem. Depending on the types of economic problems considered, economics can be divided into several branches.

In terms of the scale of economic problems considered, the subject is split into micro- and macroeconomics.

Macroeconomics studies economic behaviors of an overall economy or society. Economic choices examined here include the ones made by the national government as well as international organizations. Microeconomics considers economic problems in context of smaller entities, such as individuals or firms. Economic choices studied here concern behaviors of, and interactions between, consumers and producers of resources. The distinction between these two branches of economics is represented in the following diagram.

There are many other subdivisions in economics, which are specialized in the scope of economic problems considered. For instance, welfare economics studies various social welfare models, aiming to design an efficient economic system to deliver available resources to individuals in need. Development economics concerns developing countries and various priorities and strategies for these countries to achieve economic growth over time.

In our final example, we will consider what is studied in microeconomics.

Example 5: Distinguishing Different Fields of Economics

Which of the following best describes what is studied in microeconomics?

  • Behaviors of consumers and producers
  • General levels of economic activity
  • Evaluating the efficiency of economic decisions
  • Improving economic and social conditions

In this example, we need to identify which phrase best describes the study of microeconomics. Recall that we have encountered several branches of economics: macroeconomics, microeconomics, welfare economics, and development economics. Let us match each subject with the topics in the options.

Option A: Behaviors of consumers and producers lead to small-scale economic problems, which are studied in microeconomics. Hence, this option describes what is studied in microeconomics.

Option B: General levels of economic activity describe the types and quantities of economic activities in a large population, which lead to large-scale economic problems. We recall that macroeconomics mainly deals with large-scale economic problems at regional, national, or international levels. Hence, this is a topic studied in macroeconomics.

Option C: Efficiency of economic decisions involves reducing waste when allocating limited resources. This topic often arises when considering different social welfare models, where resources should be delivered to individuals in need with as little waste as possible. Such problems are studied in welfare economics.

Option D: Recall that development economics addresses various priorities and strategies for developing countries to achieve economic growth. This involves improving economic and social conditions of developing countries; hence, this is a topic of development economics.

Option A, behaviors of consumers and producers, best describes what is studied in microeconomics.

Let us finish by recapping a few important concepts from this explainer.

  • The fundamental economic problem states that human needs are diverse and continuously increasing, while resources to satisfy them are limited.
  • Individuals or economic entities can address the fundamental economic problem by making economic choices. The objective of any economic choice is to allocate the limited resources to maximize benefits.
  • Opportunity costs are the effects or consequences of alternative options in an economic choice. If the effects are financial, the opportunity cost can be written as a difference between the alternate and chosen options. Some opportunity costs are qualitative and many do not involve financial implications.
  • The efficiency of an economic system is largely determined by the ability to obtain accurate and appropriate information when making economic choices. Information failure is the deficiency in available information necessary for making economic choices.
  • Macroeconomics studies economic behaviors of an overall economy or society.
  • Microeconomics considers economic problems in the context of smaller entities, such as individuals or firms.
  • Welfare economics studies various social welfare models, aiming to design an efficient economic system to deliver available resources to individuals in need.
  • Development economics concerns developing countries and various priorities and strategies for these countries to achieve economic growth over time.

Join Nagwa Classes

Attend live sessions on Nagwa Classes to boost your learning with guidance and advice from an expert teacher!

  • Interactive Sessions
  • Chat & Messaging
  • Realistic Exam Questions
  • macOS Apple Silicon
  • macOS Intel

economics problem solving example

Nagwa uses cookies to ensure you get the best experience on our website. Learn more about our Privacy Policy

Login to your account

Change password, your password must have 8 characters or more and contain 3 of the following:.

  • a lower case character, 
  • an upper case character, 
  • a special character 

Password Changed Successfully

Your password has been changed

Create a new account

Can't sign in? Forgot your password?

Enter your email address below and we will send you the reset instructions

If the address matches an existing account you will receive an email with instructions to reset your password

Request Username

Can't sign in? Forgot your username?

Enter your email address below and we will send you your username

If the address matches an existing account you will receive an email with instructions to retrieve your username

World Scientific

  •   
  • Institutional Access

Cookies Notification

CONNECT Login Notice

Our site uses Javascript to enchance its usability. You can disable your ad blocker or whitelist our website www.worldscientific.com to view the full content.

Select your blocker:, adblock plus instructions.

  • Click the AdBlock Plus icon in the extension bar
  • Click the blue power button
  • Click refresh

Adblock Instructions

  • Click the AdBlock icon
  • Click "Don't run on pages on this site"

uBlock Origin Instructions

  • Click on the uBlock Origin icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the big, blue power button
  • Refresh the web page

uBlock Instructions

  • Click on the uBlock icon in the extension bar

Adguard Instructions

  • Click on the Adguard icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the toggle next to the "Protection on this website" text

Brave Instructions

  • Click on the orange lion icon to the right of the address bar
  • Click the toggle on the top right, shifting from "Up" to "Down

Adremover Instructions

  • Click on the AdRemover icon in the extension bar
  • Click the "Don’t run on pages on this domain" button
  • Click "Exclude"

Adblock Genesis Instructions

  • Click on the Adblock Genesis icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the button that says "Whitelist Website"

Super Adblocker Instructions

  • Click on the Super Adblocker icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the "Don’t run on pages on this domain" button
  • Click the "Exclude" button on the pop-up

Ultrablock Instructions

  • Click on the UltraBlock icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the "Disable UltraBlock for ‘domain name here’" button

Ad Aware Instructions

  • Click on the AdAware icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the large orange power button

Ghostery Instructions

  • Click on the Ghostery icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the "Trust Site" button

Firefox Tracking Protection Instructions

  • Click on the shield icon on the left side of the address bar
  • Click on the toggle that says "Enhanced Tracking protection is ON for this site"

Duck Duck Go Instructions

  • Click on the DuckDuckGo icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the toggle next to the words "Site Privacy Protection"

Privacy Badger Instructions

  • Click on the Privacy Badger icon in the extension bar
  • Click on the button that says "Disable Privacy Badger for this site"

Disconnect Instructions

  • Click on the Disconnect icon in the extension bar
  • Click the button that says "Whitelist Site"

Opera Instructions

  • Click on the blue shield icon on the right side of the address bar
  • Click the toggle next to "Ads are blocked on this site"

System Upgrade on Tue, May 28th, 2024 at 2am (EDT)

Problem Solving in Economics cover

Problem Solving in Economics

  • By (author): 
  • Monojit Chatterji ( University of Cambridge, UK )
  • Add to favorites
  • Download Citations
  • Track Citations
  • Recommend to Library
  • Description
  • Supplementary

This book reinforces an understanding of Economics by showing how basic mathematics is used to construct models of the economy. By taking wide-ranging examples drawn for virtually all areas of economics, it shows how model-building is an indispensable aid to understanding economics.

The mathematical techniques used in the book are fairly rudimentary — optimisation methods and equation-solving are the primary tools used. A brief explanation of constrained optimisation using Lagrange multipliers is provided. Throughout, the emphasis is on how these techniques are fruitfully deployed in constructing economic models and solving economic problems. It bridges the gap between mathematical analysis and economic logic. For readers, it builds confidence in constructing their own models for purposes of analysis. The book is well-suited for self-study.

Request Inspection Copy

Sample Chapter(s) Preface Chapter 1: Fundamental Concepts of Consumer Theory

  • Budget Sets
  • Consumer Preferences
  • Utility and Preferences
  • Consumer Optimum
  • Demand Analysis
  • Demand and Decomposition
  • Some Special Cases
  • Responsiveness of Demand
  • Labour Supply
  • Endogenous Income
  • Costs and Technology
  • Costs: Total, Average and Margin Functions
  • Costs in the Short and Long Run
  • The Significance of Fixed Costs
  • The Supply Curve of the Firm
  • The Market Demand and Supply Curves
  • Elasticity: Alternate Measures and Applications
  • Short-Run Equilibrium Price
  • Consumer and Producer Surplus
  • Taxation and Competitive Markets
  • Long-Run Equilibrium in Competitive Markets
  • Duopoly and Oligopoly
  • Discriminating Monopoly
  • Discounting, Interest Rate and Budget Line
  • Discounting and Preferences
  • Inter-Temporal Consumer Optimum
  • Saving and Investment
  • Efficiency and Planning
  • The Contract Curve and Welfare Theorems
  • Production and Planning: the Robinson Crusoe Economy
  • Production and Competition in the Robinson Crusoe Economy
  • Efficiency and Competition with Increasing Returns
  • Externalities and the Environment
  • National Income
  • Comparing National Incomes
  • Labour Market Measures
  • Measuring Economic Growth
  • Behavioural Equations, Structure and Reduced Form
  • The Method of Comparative Statics
  • More Complex Models
  • Labour Demand
  • Market Equilibrium
  • Unemployment
  • The Goods Market
  • Real and Nominal Rates of Interest
  • Money and the Price Level
  • Overview and Classical Dichotomy
  • The Simple Keynesian Model
  • Investment Functions and Goods Market Equilibrium
  • The Money Market
  • Output and Employment in the Generalised Keynesian Model
  • Fiscal Policy
  • Changing the Money Supply
  • Changing the Interest Rate
  • Aggregate Supply, Aggregate Demand and Inflation
  • Exchange Rates
  • Exports, Imports and Capital Flows
  • The Open Macroeconomy: Floating Exchange Rates
  • The Open Macroeconomy: Fixed Exchange Rates
  • Basic Growth Concepts
  • Production and Technology
  • Capital Accumulation
  • Steady State and Dynamics
  • The Golden Rule

Readership: This book will be of primary interest to students. It starts at a basic level but smoothly climbs into more advanced topics. So, it can profitably be used not only by starting and intermediate undergraduates but also by graduates seeking to convert from another subject to Economics.

FRONT MATTER

  • Pages: i–xiv

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_fmatter

  • About the Author

Chapter 1: Fundamental Concepts of Consumer Theory

  • Pages: 1–18

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0001

The conventional economic model of the consumer postulates a self-seeking individual who does the best she can, subject to affordability. When faced with a choice of how much of each good to buy, the consumer chooses the “best” bundle of goods that is affordable. We start by focusing on a precise meaning of affordability leaving a description of what is meant by the “best” till later.

Chapter 2: Consumer Optimum and Demand

  • Pages: 19–42

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0002

In this chapter, we use the concepts developed in Chapter 1 to analyse the consumer’s optimum choice bundle. Specifically, we will address the question of how the consumer’s optimum bundle is characterised and whether the characterisation depends on the nature of preferences (utility function). We illustrate different possibilities in the examples. We also create examples to illustrate how the optimum changes as prices or money income change.

Chapter 3: Generalisations, Applications and Extensions of the Choice Model

  • Pages: 43–53

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0003

In the analysis of consumer choice, we focused a lot on the tangency solution. Our analysis was restricted to the two good cases, and the “derivation” of the tangency condition was essentially geometric intuition. Furthermore, in all the examples so far, the constraint was essentially linear. Before looking at further applications and extensions, it would be helpful to sketch a general solution method which works with more than two variables and also can encompass nonlinear constraints. The treatment of this important problem is heuristic rather than rigorous. We focus on how to use the method…

Chapter 4: The Firm: Technology, Costs and Supply

  • Pages: 55–72

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0004

In this chapter, we begin our analysis of the behaviour of another major player: the business firm.

Chapter 5: Demand, Supply and the Competitive Market

  • Pages: 73–92

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0005

In Chapter 3, we saw how to derive an individual’s demand curve for a commodity starting from their preferences, their income and the market price. Holding all else constant, the demand curve for a price-taking utility maximising individual shows the quantity demanded by the individual at every conceivable market price. The inverse demand curve expresses the same relationship with price as the dependent variable and quantity as the independent variable. Similarly, in Chapter 4, we saw how to derive an individual firm’s supply curve for a commodity starting from their technology, factor prices and the market price of the commodity. Holding all else constant, the supply curve for a price-taking firm relates the quantity supplied by the profit-maximising firm at every conceivable market price. The inverse supply curve expresses the same relationship with price as the dependent variable and quantity as the independent variable. In this chapter, we use these ideas to discuss the configurations that arise when we consider many price-taking consumers and many price-taking firms to arrive at market demand and supply. We will study the market equilibrium and how it changes in both the short and the long run.

Chapter 6: Market Power and Imperfect Competition

  • Pages: 93–107

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0006

In the previous chapter, we analysed equilibrium price–quantity configurations in a competitive market. The essence of such a market is that each agent — firm and consumer — takes market price as given and reacts to it by choosing a quantity to sell or buy. In effect, this means no agent has any market power to influence the price. In this chapter, we look at situations where at least one agent has market power and can directly influence the price. We will focus on firms as the agents possessing market power. Examples of consumer market power (through consumer associations, etc.) are rare. There are many different ways in which economists have conceived the market power of firms. We shall look at the most common forms in this chapter.

Chapter 7: Inter-temporal Economics

  • Pages: 109–124

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0007

In the previous chapters, we assumed that decision-making never involved commodities beyond a single period, i.e., today. However, there are very important decisions which by their nature are spread over time. Examples include how to balance present with future consumption. One strategy is to save (consume less than current income) today and invest the savings to generate income for future consumption. We start by assuming that the decisions to save and invest are carried out by the same agent. We further imagine that there are only two periods of time which we call the “current” or “today” (period 0) and the “future” or “tomorrow” (period 1). In reality, the future consists of many periods but nothing conceptually important is lost by the simplicity of the two-period model. We assume there is only one good called corn which can be consumed today or tomorrow.

Chapter 8: Coordination of Exchange and Production

  • Pages: 125–157

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0008

In all economies, there are many economic agents taking decisions simultaneously. Consumers are deciding what to buy, how much to save, etc. Firms are deciding what and how much to produce and sell, how much to invest, how many workers and machines to hire, etc. In this chapter, we study the issue of how such myriad decision-making is coordinated. Do we get order or chaos? We will analyse the role played by markets and a planner in coordination…

Chapter 9: Macroeconomic Concepts and Measurement

  • Pages: 159–167

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0009

Macroeconomics is concerned with the analysis of aggregate variables which affect human well-being. In particular, we will focus on the determinants of the level and growth of national income, the price index and inflation, employment and unemployment, and the balance of our economic relationships with other countries. The role of government in policymaking intended to improve macroeconomic outcomes is a central part of the analysis. In all economies, there are many economic agents taking decisions simultaneously. Consumers/workers are deciding what to buy, how much to save, how much to work, etc. Firms (including banks) are deciding what and how much to produce and sell, how much to invest, how many workers and machines to hire, etc. Government seeks to influence these decisions by changing the environment in which the private sector (consumers/workers and firms) operates.

Chapter 10: Equilibrium and Comparative Statics in Macro Models

  • Pages: 169–179

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0010

When macroeconomists seek to analyse the economy, they construct a little miniature of the economy which embodies the key features of interest. Such an artificial construction is called a model. Typically, a model will consist of a set of equations that link the variables of interest. These equations are usually of two types. The first type is what is called an equilibrium condition. The concept of equilibrium is fundamental to a study of economics. An equilibrium is a situation in which there is no force for change — a situation which can be sustained. For example, in macroeconomics, a situation where planned expenditure equals national income is often described as an equilibrium. In later chapters, we will show how this can be justified. For now, we simply assume that planned expenditure equals national income represents a macroeconomic equilibrium. Denoting national income by Y , consumption by C and investment by I , then in a simple closed economy with no foreign trade, planned expenditure Z is simply the sum of consumption and investment. The equilibrium condition in this particularly simple economy is thus Z = C + I = Y or Y   =   C   +   I .           (10 .1) …

Chapter 11: The Classical Labour Market

  • Pages: 181–197

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0011

This model of the labour market has enjoyed popularity for a considerable length of time. It is based on the idea of perfect competition which implies that all agents in the market are price takers. The price-taking assumption means that agents take the price as given and simply choose optimising quantities in the belief that any action they take cannot influence the price. At its simplest, the agents are of two opposite types. First, there are firms which use labour (together with other inputs) to produce output which is sold in the search for profits. This is the source of the demand for labour. On the other side are workers. They supply labour in return for remuneration which finances their consumption. Given relevant prices, firms only have to choose how much labour to hire while workers have to decide whether to work or not.

Chapter 12: The Classical Model of Money, Interest and the Price Level

  • Pages: 199–216

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0012

In the previous chapter, we showed how real wage flexibility determines both the level of employment and output. In this chapter, we extend the analysis to the other main macroeconomic variables, namely interest rates and the price level. The role of the money supply is emphasised particularly in the determination of the price level. We assume a closed economy in which there is no foreign trade. And in the spirit of the classical theory, we assume all relevant prices are fully flexible.

Chapter 13: Sticky Prices and Keynesian Macroeconomics

  • Pages: 217–235

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0013

In the previous two chapters, we analysed the macroeconomy from the classical perspective which is based on the presumption of fully flexible real prices. In particular, we showed how real wage flexibility determines both the level of employment and output in the labour market. In this chapter, we explore another view — one associated with John Maynard Keynes and referred to as Keynesian macroeconomics. The essence of this view is that real and nominal prices are sticky, even rigid and do not adjust at least in the short run. Hence, output is not predetermined by the prior determination of employment in the labour market. On the contrary, it is output that determines employment.

Chapter 14: Monetary Economics

  • Pages: 237–250

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0014

In the previous chapter, we analysed the role of Fiscal Policy — government spending and tax — on the macroeconomy from the Keynesian perspective which is based on the presumption of fixed price level in the short run. We saw that changes in government spending and taxation or both can influence output and hence employment. The size of the impact — the multipliers — was dependent on how government spending was financed. In this chapter, we extend the ideas of the previous chapter to focus on monetary policy. Initially, we take monetary policy to mean a change in money supply M s brought about by the Central Bank (CB). The CB does this by buying government bonds from or selling government bonds to the public. CB sale of bonds reduces money supply while CB purchase of bonds increases money supply. If the price level P is fixed, then every change in nominal money supply M s produces a similar change in the real money supply M r because M r = M s / P .

Chapter 15: Open Economy Macroeconomics

  • Pages: 251–266

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0015

Up to now, the fact that most countries trade with each other has been ignored. In this chapter, we consider how international factors influence the macroeconomy and may constrain macroeconomic policy options. We consider the case of a small open economy, like the UK. The small open economy cannot influence the world economy but is influenced by events and policies in the world economy. For ease of exposition, we consider the macroeconomics of a domestic small open economy (the UK prototype) trading with the large “rest of the world economy” which we call ROW. The currency of the domestic economy is pounds (£) and that of ROW is dollars ($). They are linked by the concept of the exchange rate.

Chapter 16: Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth

  • Pages: 267–279

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_0016

In our analysis of macroeconomics so far, we have distinguished between the short run and the long run. The short run is conceived as a period of time in which prices are fixed and cannot change. By contrast, the long run has been conceived of as a period of time in which prices can fully adjust. However, both in the short-run as well as in the long-run analyses, we have maintained the implicit assumption that the productive capacity of the economy is unchanged. The capital stock is assumed to be constant. Investment adds to aggregate demand but its impact on capital accumulation and hence capacity has been ignored. In this chapter, we analyse the role of capital accumulation in moving the economy forward. Investment is the source of additions to the capital stock or capital accumulation. This in turn leads to greater output which in turn leads to greater savings. If these savings are partly or wholly converted into investment, the process continues driving output upwards. This may be thought of as the economics of the very long run.

BACK MATTER

  • Pages: 281–288

https://doi.org/10.1142/9789811273360_bmatter

economics problem solving example

Module: Economic Thinking

Problem set: math in economics.

Test your understanding of the learning outcomes in this module by working through the following problems. These problems aren’t graded, but they give you a chance to practice before taking the quiz.

If you’d like to try a problem again, you can click the link that reads, “Try another version of this question.”

  • Problem Set: Math in Economics. Provided by : Lumen Learning. License : CC BY: Attribution

1.1 What Is Economics, and Why Is It Important?

Learning objectives.

By the end of this section, you will be able to:

  • Discuss the importance of studying economics
  • Explain the relationship between production and division of labor
  • Evaluate the significance of scarcity

Economics is the study of how humans make decisions in the face of scarcity. These can be individual decisions, family decisions, business decisions or societal decisions. If you look around carefully, you will see that scarcity is a fact of life. Scarcity means that human wants for goods, services and resources exceed what is available. Resources, such as labor, tools, land, and raw materials are necessary to produce the goods and services we want but they exist in limited supply. Of course, the ultimate scarce resource is time- everyone, rich or poor, has just 24 expendable hours in the day to earn income to acquire goods and services, for leisure time, or for sleep. At any point in time, there is only a finite amount of resources available.

Think about it this way: In 2015 the labor force in the United States contained over 158 million workers, according to the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. The total land area was 3,794,101 square miles. While these are certainly large numbers, they are not infinite. Because these resources are limited, so are the numbers of goods and services we produce with them. Combine this with the fact that human wants seem to be virtually infinite, and you can see why scarcity is a problem.

Introduction to FRED

Data is very important in economics because it describes and measures the issues and problems that economics seek to understand. A variety of government agencies publish economic and social data. For this course, we will generally use data from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank's FRED database. FRED is very user friendly. It allows you to display data in tables or charts, and you can easily download it into spreadsheet form if you want to use the data for other purposes. The FRED website includes data on nearly 400,000 domestic and international variables over time, in the following broad categories:

  • Money, Banking & Finance
  • Population, Employment, & Labor Markets (including Income Distribution)
  • National Accounts (Gross Domestic Product & its components), Flow of Funds, and International Accounts
  • Production & Business Activity (including Business Cycles)
  • Prices & Inflation (including the Consumer Price Index, the Producer Price Index, and the Employment Cost Index)
  • International Data from other nations
  • U.S. Regional Data
  • Academic Data (including Penn World Tables & NBER Macrohistory database)

For more information about how to use FRED, see the variety of videos on YouTube starting with this introduction.

If you still do not believe that scarcity is a problem, consider the following: Does everyone require food to eat? Does everyone need a decent place to live? Does everyone have access to healthcare? In every country in the world, there are people who are hungry, homeless (for example, those who call park benches their beds, as Figure 1.2 shows), and in need of healthcare, just to focus on a few critical goods and services. Why is this the case? It is because of scarcity. Let’s delve into the concept of scarcity a little deeper, because it is crucial to understanding economics.

The Problem of Scarcity

Think about all the things you consume: food, shelter, clothing, transportation, healthcare, and entertainment. How do you acquire those items? You do not produce them yourself. You buy them. How do you afford the things you buy? You work for pay. If you do not, someone else does on your behalf. Yet most of us never have enough income to buy all the things we want. This is because of scarcity. So how do we solve it?

Visit this website to read about how the United States is dealing with scarcity in resources.

Every society, at every level, must make choices about how to use its resources. Families must decide whether to spend their money on a new car or a fancy vacation. Towns must choose whether to put more of the budget into police and fire protection or into the school system. Nations must decide whether to devote more funds to national defense or to protecting the environment. In most cases, there just isn’t enough money in the budget to do everything. How do we use our limited resources the best way possible, that is, to obtain the most goods and services we can? There are a couple of options. First, we could each produce everything we each consume. Alternatively, we could each produce some of what we want to consume, and “trade” for the rest of what we want. Let’s explore these options. Why do we not each just produce all of the things we consume? Think back to pioneer days, when individuals knew how to do so much more than we do today, from building their homes, to growing their crops, to hunting for food, to repairing their equipment. Most of us do not know how to do all—or any—of those things, but it is not because we could not learn. Rather, we do not have to. The reason why is something called the division and specialization of labor , a production innovation first put forth by Adam Smith ( Figure 1.3 ) in his book, The Wealth of Nations .

The Division of and Specialization of Labor

The formal study of economics began when Adam Smith (1723–1790) published his famous book The Wealth of Nations in 1776. Many authors had written on economics in the centuries before Smith, but he was the first to address the subject in a comprehensive way. In the first chapter, Smith introduces the concept of division of labor , which means that the way one produces a good or service is divided into a number of tasks that different workers perform, instead of all the tasks being done by the same person.

To illustrate division of labor, Smith counted how many tasks went into making a pin: drawing out a piece of wire, cutting it to the right length, straightening it, putting a head on one end and a point on the other, and packaging pins for sale, to name just a few. Smith counted 18 distinct tasks that different people performed—all for a pin, believe it or not!

Modern businesses divide tasks as well. Even a relatively simple business like a restaurant divides the task of serving meals into a range of jobs like top chef, sous chefs, less-skilled kitchen help, servers to wait on the tables, a greeter at the door, janitors to clean up, and a business manager to handle paychecks and bills—not to mention the economic connections a restaurant has with suppliers of food, furniture, kitchen equipment, and the building where it is located. A complex business like a large manufacturing factory, such as the shoe factory ( Figure 1.4 ), or a hospital can have hundreds of job classifications.

Why the Division of Labor Increases Production

When we divide and subdivide the tasks involved with producing a good or service, workers and businesses can produce a greater quantity of output. In his observations of pin factories, Smith noticed that one worker alone might make 20 pins in a day, but that a small business of 10 workers (some of whom would need to complete two or three of the 18 tasks involved with pin-making), could make 48,000 pins in a day. How can a group of workers, each specializing in certain tasks, produce so much more than the same number of workers who try to produce the entire good or service by themselves? Smith offered three reasons.

First, specialization in a particular small job allows workers to focus on the parts of the production process where they have an advantage. (In later chapters, we will develop this idea by discussing comparative advantage .) People have different skills, talents, and interests, so they will be better at some jobs than at others. The particular advantages may be based on educational choices, which are in turn shaped by interests and talents. Only those with medical degrees qualify to become doctors, for instance. For some goods, geography affects specialization. For example, it is easier to be a wheat farmer in North Dakota than in Florida, but easier to run a tourist hotel in Florida than in North Dakota. If you live in or near a big city, it is easier to attract enough customers to operate a successful dry cleaning business or movie theater than if you live in a sparsely populated rural area. Whatever the reason, if people specialize in the production of what they do best, they will be more effective than if they produce a combination of things, some of which they are good at and some of which they are not.

Second, workers who specialize in certain tasks often learn to produce more quickly and with higher quality. This pattern holds true for many workers, including assembly line laborers who build cars, stylists who cut hair, and doctors who perform heart surgery. In fact, specialized workers often know their jobs well enough to suggest innovative ways to do their work faster and better.

A similar pattern often operates within businesses. In many cases, a business that focuses on one or a few products (sometimes called its “ core competency ”) is more successful than firms that try to make a wide range of products.

Third, specialization allows businesses to take advantage of economies of scale , which means that for many goods, as the level of production increases, the average cost of producing each individual unit declines. For example, if a factory produces only 100 cars per year, each car will be quite expensive to make on average. However, if a factory produces 50,000 cars each year, then it can set up an assembly line with huge machines and workers performing specialized tasks, and the average cost of production per car will be lower. The ultimate result of workers who can focus on their preferences and talents, learn to do their specialized jobs better, and work in larger organizations is that society as a whole can produce and consume far more than if each person tried to produce all of their own goods and services. The division and specialization of labor has been a force against the problem of scarcity.

Trade and Markets

Specialization only makes sense, though, if workers can use the pay they receive for doing their jobs to purchase the other goods and services that they need. In short, specialization requires trade.

You do not have to know anything about electronics or sound systems to play music—you just buy an iPod or MP3 player, download the music, and listen. You do not have to know anything about artificial fibers or the construction of sewing machines if you need a jacket—you just buy the jacket and wear it. You do not need to know anything about internal combustion engines to operate a car—you just get in and drive. Instead of trying to acquire all the knowledge and skills involved in producing all of the goods and services that you wish to consume, the market allows you to learn a specialized set of skills and then use the pay you receive to buy the goods and services you need or want. This is how our modern society has evolved into a strong economy.

Why Study Economics?

Now that you have an overview on what economics studies, let’s quickly discuss why you are right to study it. Economics is not primarily a collection of facts to memorize, although there are plenty of important concepts to learn. Instead, think of economics as a collection of questions to answer or puzzles to work. Most importantly, economics provides the tools to solve those puzzles.

Consider the complex and critical issue of education barriers on national and regional levels, which affect millions of people and result in widespread poverty and inequality. Governments, aid organizations, and wealthy individuals spend billions of dollars each year trying to address these issues. Nations announce the revitalization of their education programs; tech companies donate devices and infrastructure, and celebrities and charities build schools and sponsor students. Yet the problems remain, sometimes almost as pronounced as they were before the intervention. Why is that the case? In 2019, three economists—Esther Duflo, Abhijit Banerjee, and Michael Kremer—were awarded the Nobel Prize for their work to answer those questions. They worked diligently to break the widespread problems into smaller pieces, and experimented with small interventions to test success. The award citation credited their work with giving the world better tools and information to address poverty and improve education. Esther Duflo, who is the youngest person and second woman to win the Nobel Prize in Economics, said, "We believed that like the war on cancer, the war on poverty was not going to be won in one major battle, but in a series of small triumphs. . . . This work and the culture of learning that it fostered in governments has led to real improvement in the lives of hundreds of millions of poor people.”

As you can see, economics affects far more than business. For example:

  • Virtually every major problem facing the world today, from global warming, to world poverty, to the conflicts in Syria, Afghanistan, and Somalia, has an economic dimension. If you are going to be part of solving those problems, you need to be able to understand them. Economics is crucial.
  • It is hard to overstate the importance of economics to good citizenship. You need to be able to vote intelligently on budgets, regulations, and laws in general. When the U.S. government came close to a standstill at the end of 2012 due to the “fiscal cliff,” what were the issues? Did you know?
  • A basic understanding of economics makes you a well-rounded thinker. When you read articles about economic issues, you will understand and be able to evaluate the writer’s argument. When you hear classmates, co-workers, or political candidates talking about economics, you will be able to distinguish between common sense and nonsense. You will find new ways of thinking about current events and about personal and business decisions, as well as current events and politics.

The study of economics does not dictate the answers, but it can illuminate the different choices.

As an Amazon Associate we earn from qualifying purchases.

This book may not be used in the training of large language models or otherwise be ingested into large language models or generative AI offerings without OpenStax's permission.

Want to cite, share, or modify this book? This book uses the Creative Commons Attribution License and you must attribute OpenStax.

Access for free at https://openstax.org/books/principles-economics-3e/pages/1-introduction
  • Authors: Steven A. Greenlaw, David Shapiro, Daniel MacDonald
  • Publisher/website: OpenStax
  • Book title: Principles of Economics 3e
  • Publication date: Dec 14, 2022
  • Location: Houston, Texas
  • Book URL: https://openstax.org/books/principles-economics-3e/pages/1-introduction
  • Section URL: https://openstax.org/books/principles-economics-3e/pages/1-1-what-is-economics-and-why-is-it-important

© Jan 23, 2024 OpenStax. Textbook content produced by OpenStax is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution License . The OpenStax name, OpenStax logo, OpenStax book covers, OpenStax CNX name, and OpenStax CNX logo are not subject to the Creative Commons license and may not be reproduced without the prior and express written consent of Rice University.

Suggestions or feedback?

MIT News | Massachusetts Institute of Technology

  • Machine learning
  • Social justice
  • Black holes
  • Classes and programs

Departments

  • Aeronautics and Astronautics
  • Brain and Cognitive Sciences
  • Architecture
  • Political Science
  • Mechanical Engineering

Centers, Labs, & Programs

  • Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab (J-PAL)
  • Picower Institute for Learning and Memory
  • Lincoln Laboratory
  • School of Architecture + Planning
  • School of Engineering
  • School of Humanities, Arts, and Social Sciences
  • Sloan School of Management
  • School of Science
  • MIT Schwarzman College of Computing

The power of economics to explain and shape the world

Press contact :.

Photo of Abijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo standing side-by-side against a blurred background

Previous image Next image

Nobel Prize-winning economist Esther Duflo sympathizes with students who have no interest in her field. She was such a student herself — until an undergraduate research post gave her the chance to learn first-hand that economists address many of the major issues facing human and planetary well-being. “Most people have a wrong view of what economics is. They just see economists on television discussing what’s going to happen to the stock market,” says Duflo, the Abdul Latif Jameel Professor of Poverty Alleviation and Development Economics. “But what people do in the field is very broad. Economists grapple with the real world and with the complexity that goes with it.”

That’s why this year Duflo has teamed up with Professor Abhijit Banerjee to offer 14.009 (Economics and Society’s Greatest Problems), a first-year discovery subject — a class type designed to give undergraduates a low-pressure, high-impact way to explore a field. In this case, they are exploring the range of issues that economists engage with every day: the economic dimensions of climate change, international trade, racism, justice, education, poverty, health care, social preferences, and economic growth are just a few of the topics the class covers. “We think it’s pretty important that the first exposure to economics is via issues,” Duflo says. “If you first get exposed to economics via models, these models necessarily have to be very simplified, and then students get the idea that economics is a simplistic view of the world that can’t explain much.” Arguably, Duflo and Banerjee have been disproving that view throughout their careers. In 2003, the pair founded MIT’s Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab, a leading antipoverty research network that provides scientific evidence on what methods actually work to alleviate poverty — which enables governments and nongovernmental organizations to implement truly effective programs and social policies. And, in 2019 they won the Nobel Prize in economics (together with Michael Kremer of the University of Chicago) for their innovative work applying laboratory-style randomized, controlled trials to research a wide range of topics implicated in global poverty. “Super cool”

First-year Jean Billa, one of the students in 14.009, says, “Economics isn’t just about how money flows, but about how people react to certain events. That was an interesting discovery for me.”

It’s also precisely the lesson Banerjee and Duflo hoped students would take away from 14.009, a class that centers on weekly in-person discussions of the professors’ recorded lectures — many of which align with chapters in Banerjee and Duflo’s book “Good Economics for Hard Times” (Public Affairs, 2019). Classes typically start with a poll in which the roughly 100 enrolled students can register their views on that week’s topic. Then, students get to discuss the issue, says senior Dina Atia, teaching assistant for the class. Noting that she finds it “super cool” that Nobelists are teaching MIT’s first-year students, Atia points out that both Duflo and Banerjee have also made themselves available to chat with students after class. “They’re definitely extending themselves,” she says. “We want the students to get excited about economics so they want to know more,” says Banerjee, the Ford Foundation International Professor of Economics, “because this is a field that can help us address some of the biggest problems society faces.”   Using natural experiments to test theories

Early in the term, for example, the topic was migration. In the lecture, Duflo points out that migration policies are often impacted by the fear that unskilled migrants will overwhelm a region, taking jobs from residents and demanding social services. Yet, migrant flows in normal years represent just 3 percent of the world population. “There is no flood. There is no vast movement of migrants,” she says. Duflo then explains that economists were able to learn a lot about migration thanks to a “natural experiment,” the Mariel boat lift. This 1980 event brought roughly 125,000 unskilled Cubans to Florida over a matter a months, enabling economists to study the impacts of a sudden wave of migration. Duflo says a look at real wages before and after the migration showed no significant impacts. “It was interesting to see that most theories about immigrants were not justified,” Billa says. “That was a real-life situation, and the results showed that even a massive wave of immigration didn’t change work in the city [Miami].”

Question assumptions, find the facts in data Since this is a broad survey course, there is always more to unpack. The goal, faculty say, is simply to help students understand the power of economics to explain and shape the world. “We are going so fast from topic to topic, I don’t expect them to retain all the information,” Duflo says. Instead, students are expected to gain an appreciation for a way of thinking. “Economics is about questioning everything — questioning assumptions you don’t even know are assumptions and being sophisticated about looking at data to uncover the facts.” To add impact, Duflo says she and Banerjee tie lessons to current events and dive more deeply into a few economic studies. One class, for example, focused on the unequal burden the Covid-19 pandemic has placed on different demographic groups and referenced research by Harvard University professor Marcella Alsan, who won a MacArthur Fellowship this fall for her work studying the impact of racism on health disparities.

Duflo also revealed that at the beginning of the pandemic, she suspected that mistrust of the health-care system could prevent Black Americans from taking certain measures to protect themselves from the virus. What she discovered when she researched the topic, however, was that political considerations outweighed racial influences as a predictor of behavior. “The lesson for you is, it’s good to question your assumptions,” she told the class. “Students should ideally understand, by the end of class, why it’s important to ask questions and what they can teach us about the effectiveness of policy and economic theory,” Banerjee says. “We want people to discover the range of economics and to understand how economists look at problems.”

Story by MIT SHASS Communications Editorial and design director: Emily Hiestand Senior writer: Kathryn O'Neill

Share this news article on:

Press mentions.

Prof. Esther Duflo will present her research on poverty reduction and her “proposal for a global minimum tax on billionaires and increased corporate levies to G-20 finance chiefs,” reports Andrew Rosati for Bloomberg. “The plan calls for redistributing the revenues to low- and middle-income nations to compensate for lives lost due to a warming planet,” writes Rosati. “It also adds to growing calls to raise taxes on the world’s wealthiest to help its most needy.”

Previous item Next item

Related Links

  • Class 14.009 (Economics and Society’s Greatest Problems)
  • Esther Duflo
  • Abhijit Banerjee
  • Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab
  • Department of Economics
  • Video: "Lighting the Path"

Related Topics

  • Education, teaching, academics
  • Climate change
  • Immigration
  • Health care
  • School of Humanities Arts and Social Sciences

Related Articles

Asu Ozdaglar,

Popular new major blends technical skills and human-centered applications

migration group

Report: Economics drives migration from Central America to the U.S.

MIT economists Abhijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo stand outside their home after learning that they have been named co-winners of the 2019 Nobel Prize in economic sciences. They will share the prize with Michael Kremer of Harvard University.

MIT economists Esther Duflo and Abhijit Banerjee win Nobel Prize

More mit news.

Isaiah Andrews sits outside at MIT campus.

Through econometrics, Isaiah Andrews is making research more robust

Read full story →

A rendering shows the MIT campus and Cambridge, with MIT buildings in red.

Students research pathways for MIT to reach decarbonization goals

Namrata Kala sits in glass-walled building

Improving working environments amid environmental distress

Ashesh Rambachan converses with a student in the front of a classroom.

A data-driven approach to making better choices

On the left, Erik Lin-Greenberg talks, smiling, with two graduate students in his office. On the right, Tracy Slatyer sits with two students on a staircase, conversing warmly.

Paying it forward

Portrait photo of John Fucillo posing on a indoor stairwell

John Fucillo: Laying foundations for MIT’s Department of Biology

  • More news on MIT News homepage →

Massachusetts Institute of Technology 77 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA, USA

  • Map (opens in new window)
  • Events (opens in new window)
  • People (opens in new window)
  • Careers (opens in new window)
  • Accessibility
  • Social Media Hub
  • MIT on Facebook
  • MIT on YouTube
  • MIT on Instagram

Economics Help

Basic Economic Problem

  • The fundamental economic problem is the issue of scarcity and how best to produce and distribute these scare resources .
  • Scarcity means there is a finite supply of goods and raw materials.
  • Finite resources mean they are limited and can run out.
  • Unlimited wants mean that there is no end to the quantity of goods and services people would like to consume.
  • Because of unlimited wants – People would like to consume more than it is possible to produce (scarcity)

Fundamental economic question

economics problem solving example

Therefore because of scarcity, economics is concerned with:

  • What to produce?
  • How to produce?

Examples of the economic problem

Households have limited income and they need to decide how to spend their finite income. For example, with an annual income of £20,000, a household may need to spend £10,000 a year on rent, council tax and utility bills. This leaves £10,000 for deciding which other food, clothes, transport and other goods to purchase.

Householders will also face decisions on how much to work. For example, working overtime at the weekend will give them extra income to spend, but less leisure time to enjoy it. A worker may also wish to spend more time in learning new skills and qualifications. This may limit their earning power in the short-term, but enable a greater earning power in the long-term.  For example, at 18 a student could go straight into work or they could go to university where they will hope to gain a degree and more earning power in the long-term.

A producer needs to remain profitable (revenue higher than costs). So it will need to produce the goods which are in high demand and respond to changing demands and buying habits of consumers – for example, switching to online sales as the high street declines. Producers will need to constantly ask the best way of producing goods. For example, purchasing new machines can increase productivity and enable the firms to produce goods at a lower cost. This is important for fast-changing industries where new technology is frequently reducing costs of production. Without firms adapting to how they produce, they can become unprofitable.

Firms may also need to make long-term investment decisions to invest in new products and new means of production.

The government has finite resources and its spending power is limited by the amount of tax that they can collect. The government needs to decide how they collect tax and then they need to decide whom they spend money on. For example, the government may wish to cut benefits to those on low income to increase incentives to work. However, cutting benefits will increase inequality and relative poverty.

Opportunity cost and the economic problem

The economic problem can be illustrated with the concept of opportunity cost.

Opportunity cost is the next best alternative foregone. A consumer with a limited income of £20,000 year continually faces choices, if they spend £3,000 on a new car, then that is £3,000 they cannot spend on food and drink

If a student spends three years in education, the opportunity cost is the lost potential of earning from a full-time job.

A government may have choices on how to spend limited resources. In this simple model, they have a choice between health care and military spending. If they increase spending on the military, the opportunity cost is less spending on health care.

ppf-curve-health-military

If you're seeing this message, it means we're having trouble loading external resources on our website.

If you're behind a web filter, please make sure that the domains *.kastatic.org and *.kasandbox.org are unblocked.

To log in and use all the features of Khan Academy, please enable JavaScript in your browser.

AP®︎/College Macroeconomics

Course: ap®︎/college macroeconomics   >   unit 1.

  • Introduction to economics
  • Four factors of production
  • Normative and positive statements
  • Economic models

Lesson summary: Introduction to Macroeconomics

  • Introduction to scarcity and the economic way of thinking

economics problem solving example

  • What will be produced with society’s limited resources?
  • How will we produce the things we need and want?
  • How will society’s output be distributed?
TermDefinition
the study of how individuals and societies choose to allocate scarce resources.
the fact that there is a limited amount of resources to satisfy unlimited wants.
also called the ; these are the land (natural resources such as minerals and oil), labor (work contributed by humans), capital (tools, equipment, and facilities), and entrepreneurship (the capacity to organize, develop, and manage a business) that individuals and businesses use in the production of goods and services.
graphical and mathematical tools created by economists to better understand complicated processes in economics.
a Latin phrase meaning "all else equal".
some entity making a decision; this can be an individual, a household, a business, a city, or even the government of a country.
rewards or punishments associated with a possible action; agents make decisions based on incentives.
an agent is "rational" if they use all available information to choose an action that makes them as well off as possible; economic models assume that agents are rational.
analytical thinking about objective facts and cause-and-effect relationships that are testable, such as how much of a good will be sold when a price changes.
unlike positive analysis, normative analysis is subjective thinking about what we should value or a course of action that should be taken, such as the importance of environmental factors and the approach to managing them.
the study of the interactions of buyers and sellers in the markets for particular goods and services
the study of aggregates and the overall commercial output and health of nations; includes the analysis of factors such as unemployment, inflation, economic growth and interest rates.
measures such as the unemployment rate, rate of inflation, and national output that summarize all markets in an economy, rather than individual markets; economic aggregates are frequently used as measures of the economic performance of an economy.

Models and graphs

Common misperceptions.

  • Economics is not the study of stock markets, money, or how to run a business. Although many new students believe they will be learning about these concepts, economics is a social science that seeks to better understand and predict human interactions; unlike business and finance, which focus on how to manage a business organization and invest money in a way to earn the highest return for investors.
  • One essential assumption made in most economic analysis is that all humans are rational and will make choices based on what is always in their best interest. In the real world, obviously, people, businesses, and even entire societies can be highly irrational.
  • Just because a decision is "irrational" in the economic sense, that doesn't mean that it is inherently wrong, bad, or lesser than what an economist would call a "rational" decision. In fact, the field of Behavioral Economics seeks to understand better the many reasons humans choose to make economically "irrational" choices in their decision making.
  • One of the four economic resources that societies must decide how to allocate is capital . When people use the word capital in everyday conversation, many people are referring to money or “financial capital.” In economics, capital is defined as the already-produced goods (tools, machinery, equipment, and physical infrastructure) that are used in the production of other goods or services. A robot on a car factory floor is defined as capital in economics; money you borrow to start your own business is not.

Discussion questions

  • Victorian historian Thomas Carlyle once called economics the "dismal science" because he believed it obsessively focused on the scarcity of resources. What does the field of economics provide society that other sciences such as chemistry, biology and physics cannot?
  • Using at least three key terms from this lesson, explain how scarcity affects you in your everyday life.
  • What are the three basic economic questions? How have different societies that you know about or have studied in other classes attempted to answer these questions?

Want to join the conversation?

  • Upvote Button navigates to signup page
  • Downvote Button navigates to signup page
  • Flag Button navigates to signup page

Incredible Answer

Library homepage

  • school Campus Bookshelves
  • menu_book Bookshelves
  • perm_media Learning Objects
  • login Login
  • how_to_reg Request Instructor Account
  • hub Instructor Commons

Margin Size

  • Download Page (PDF)
  • Download Full Book (PDF)
  • Periodic Table
  • Physics Constants
  • Scientific Calculator
  • Reference & Cite
  • Tools expand_more
  • Readability

selected template will load here

This action is not available.

Social Sci LibreTexts

1.2: What Is Economics, and Why Is It Important?

  • Last updated
  • Save as PDF
  • Page ID 181280

\( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \)

\( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)

\( \newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)

( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\)

\( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\)

\( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\)

\( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\)

\( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)

\( \newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\)

\( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\)

\( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\)

\( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\)

\( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\)

\( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\)

\( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\)

\( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

\( \newcommand{\vectorA}[1]{\vec{#1}}      % arrow\)

\( \newcommand{\vectorAt}[1]{\vec{\text{#1}}}      % arrow\)

\( \newcommand{\vectorB}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \)

\( \newcommand{\vectorC}[1]{\textbf{#1}} \)

\( \newcommand{\vectorD}[1]{\overrightarrow{#1}} \)

\( \newcommand{\vectorDt}[1]{\overrightarrow{\text{#1}}} \)

\( \newcommand{\vectE}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash{\mathbf {#1}}}} \)

Learning Objectives

By the end of this section, you will be able to:

  • Discuss the importance of studying economics
  • Explain the relationship between production and division of labor
  • Evaluate the significance of scarcity

Economics is the study of how humans make decisions in the face of scarcity. These can be individual decisions, family decisions, business decisions or societal decisions. If you look around carefully, you will see that scarcity is a fact of life. Scarcity means that human wants for goods, services and resources exceed what is available. Resources, such as labor, tools, land, and raw materials are necessary to produce the goods and services we want but they exist in limited supply. Of course, the ultimate scarce resource is time- everyone, rich or poor, has just 24 expendable hours in the day to earn income to acquire goods and services, for leisure time, or for sleep. At any point in time, there is only a finite amount of resources available.

Think about it this way: In 2015 the labor force in the United States contained over 158 million workers, according to the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. The total land area was 3,794,101 square miles. While these are certainly large numbers, they are not infinite. Because these resources are limited, so are the numbers of goods and services we produce with them. Combine this with the fact that human wants seem to be virtually infinite, and you can see why scarcity is a problem.

Introduction to FRED

Data is very important in economics because it describes and measures the issues and problems that economics seek to understand. A variety of government agencies publish economic and social data. For this course, we will generally use data from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank's FRED database. FRED is very user friendly. It allows you to display data in tables or charts, and you can easily download it into spreadsheet form if you want to use the data for other purposes. The FRED website includes data on nearly 400,000 domestic and international variables over time, in the following broad categories:

  • Money, Banking & Finance
  • Population, Employment, & Labor Markets (including Income Distribution)
  • National Accounts (Gross Domestic Product & its components), Flow of Funds, and International Accounts
  • Production & Business Activity (including Business Cycles)
  • Prices & Inflation (including the Consumer Price Index, the Producer Price Index, and the Employment Cost Index)
  • International Data from other nations
  • U.S. Regional Data
  • Academic Data (including Penn World Tables & NBER Macrohistory database)

For more information about how to use FRED, see the variety of videos on YouTube starting with this introduction.

The image is a photograph of two people who are homeless and sleeping on public city benches.

If you still do not believe that scarcity is a problem, consider the following: Does everyone require food to eat? Does everyone need a decent place to live? Does everyone have access to healthcare? In every country in the world, there are people who are hungry, homeless (for example, those who call park benches their beds, as Figure 1.2 shows), and in need of healthcare, just to focus on a few critical goods and services. Why is this the case? It is because of scarcity. Let’s delve into the concept of scarcity a little deeper, because it is crucial to understanding economics.

The Problem of Scarcity

Think about all the things you consume: food, shelter, clothing, transportation, healthcare, and entertainment. How do you acquire those items? You do not produce them yourself. You buy them. How do you afford the things you buy? You work for pay. If you do not, someone else does on your behalf. Yet most of us never have enough income to buy all the things we want. This is because of scarcity. So how do we solve it?

Visit this website to read about how the United States is dealing with scarcity in resources.

Every society, at every level, must make choices about how to use its resources. Families must decide whether to spend their money on a new car or a fancy vacation. Towns must choose whether to put more of the budget into police and fire protection or into the school system. Nations must decide whether to devote more funds to national defense or to protecting the environment. In most cases, there just isn’t enough money in the budget to do everything. How do we use our limited resources the best way possible, that is, to obtain the most goods and services we can? There are a couple of options. First, we could each produce everything we each consume. Alternatively, we could each produce some of what we want to consume, and “trade” for the rest of what we want. Let’s explore these options. Why do we not each just produce all of the things we consume? Think back to pioneer days, when individuals knew how to do so much more than we do today, from building their homes, to growing their crops, to hunting for food, to repairing their equipment. Most of us do not know how to do all—or any—of those things, but it is not because we could not learn. Rather, we do not have to. The reason why is something called the division and specialization of labor , a production innovation first put forth by Adam Smith (Figure 1.3) in his book, The Wealth of Nations .

The image is a profile sketch of Adam Smith.

The Division of and Specialization of Labor

The formal study of economics began when Adam Smith (1723–1790) published his famous book The Wealth of Nations in 1776. Many authors had written on economics in the centuries before Smith, but he was the first to address the subject in a comprehensive way. In the first chapter, Smith introduces the concept of division of labor , which means that the way one produces a good or service is divided into a number of tasks that different workers perform, instead of all the tasks being done by the same person.

To illustrate division of labor, Smith counted how many tasks went into making a pin: drawing out a piece of wire, cutting it to the right length, straightening it, putting a head on one end and a point on the other, and packaging pins for sale, to name just a few. Smith counted 18 distinct tasks that different people performed—all for a pin, believe it or not!

Modern businesses divide tasks as well. Even a relatively simple business like a restaurant divides the task of serving meals into a range of jobs like top chef, sous chefs, less-skilled kitchen help, servers to wait on the tables, a greeter at the door, janitors to clean up, and a business manager to handle paychecks and bills—not to mention the economic connections a restaurant has with suppliers of food, furniture, kitchen equipment, and the building where it is located. A complex business like a large manufacturing factory, such as the shoe factory (Figure 1.4), or a hospital can have hundreds of job classifications.

The image is a photograph of factory workers for a shoe company working separately on individualized tasks.

Why the Division of Labor Increases Production

When we divide and subdivide the tasks involved with producing a good or service, workers and businesses can produce a greater quantity of output. In his observations of pin factories, Smith noticed that one worker alone might make 20 pins in a day, but that a small business of 10 workers (some of whom would need to complete two or three of the 18 tasks involved with pin-making), could make 48,000 pins in a day. How can a group of workers, each specializing in certain tasks, produce so much more than the same number of workers who try to produce the entire good or service by themselves? Smith offered three reasons.

First, specialization in a particular small job allows workers to focus on the parts of the production process where they have an advantage. (In later chapters, we will develop this idea by discussing comparative advantage .) People have different skills, talents, and interests, so they will be better at some jobs than at others. The particular advantages may be based on educational choices, which are in turn shaped by interests and talents. Only those with medical degrees qualify to become doctors, for instance. For some goods, geography affects specialization. For example, it is easier to be a wheat farmer in North Dakota than in Florida, but easier to run a tourist hotel in Florida than in North Dakota. If you live in or near a big city, it is easier to attract enough customers to operate a successful dry cleaning business or movie theater than if you live in a sparsely populated rural area. Whatever the reason, if people specialize in the production of what they do best, they will be more effective than if they produce a combination of things, some of which they are good at and some of which they are not.

Second, workers who specialize in certain tasks often learn to produce more quickly and with higher quality. This pattern holds true for many workers, including assembly line laborers who build cars, stylists who cut hair, and doctors who perform heart surgery. In fact, specialized workers often know their jobs well enough to suggest innovative ways to do their work faster and better.

A similar pattern often operates within businesses. In many cases, a business that focuses on one or a few products (sometimes called its “ core competency ”) is more successful than firms that try to make a wide range of products.

Third, specialization allows businesses to take advantage of economies of scale , which means that for many goods, as the level of production increases, the average cost of producing each individual unit declines. For example, if a factory produces only 100 cars per year, each car will be quite expensive to make on average. However, if a factory produces 50,000 cars each year, then it can set up an assembly line with huge machines and workers performing specialized tasks, and the average cost of production per car will be lower. The ultimate result of workers who can focus on their preferences and talents, learn to do their specialized jobs better, and work in larger organizations is that society as a whole can produce and consume far more than if each person tried to produce all of their own goods and services. The division and specialization of labor has been a force against the problem of scarcity.

Trade and Markets

Specialization only makes sense, though, if workers can use the pay they receive for doing their jobs to purchase the other goods and services that they need. In short, specialization requires trade.

You do not have to know anything about electronics or sound systems to play music—you just buy an iPod or MP3 player, download the music, and listen. You do not have to know anything about artificial fibers or the construction of sewing machines if you need a jacket—you just buy the jacket and wear it. You do not need to know anything about internal combustion engines to operate a car—you just get in and drive. Instead of trying to acquire all the knowledge and skills involved in producing all of the goods and services that you wish to consume, the market allows you to learn a specialized set of skills and then use the pay you receive to buy the goods and services you need or want. This is how our modern society has evolved into a strong economy.

Why Study Economics?

The image shows photographs of Esther Duflo, Abhijit Banerjee, and Michael Kremer.

Now that you have an overview on what economics studies, let’s quickly discuss why you are right to study it. Economics is not primarily a collection of facts to memorize, although there are plenty of important concepts to learn. Instead, think of economics as a collection of questions to answer or puzzles to work. Most importantly, economics provides the tools to solve those puzzles.

Consider the complex and critical issue of education barriers on national and regional levels, which affect millions of people and result in widespread poverty and inequality. Governments, aid organizations, and wealthy individuals spend billions of dollars each year trying to address these issues. Nations announce the revitalization of their education programs; tech companies donate devices and infrastructure, and celebrities and charities build schools and sponsor students. Yet the problems remain, sometimes almost as pronounced as they were before the intervention. Why is that the case? In 2019, three economists—Esther Duflo, Abhijit Banerjee, and Michael Kremer—were awarded the Nobel Prize for their work to answer those questions. They worked diligently to break the widespread problems into smaller pieces, and experimented with small interventions to test success. The award citation credited their work with giving the world better tools and information to address poverty and improve education. Esther Duflo, who is the youngest person and second woman to win the Nobel Prize in Economics, said, "We believed that like the war on cancer, the war on poverty was not going to be won in one major battle, but in a series of small triumphs. . . . This work and the culture of learning that it fostered in governments has led to real improvement in the lives of hundreds of millions of poor people.”

As you can see, economics affects far more than business. For example:

  • Virtually every major problem facing the world today, from global warming, to world poverty, to the conflicts in Syria, Afghanistan, and Somalia, has an economic dimension. If you are going to be part of solving those problems, you need to be able to understand them. Economics is crucial.
  • It is hard to overstate the importance of economics to good citizenship. You need to be able to vote intelligently on budgets, regulations, and laws in general. When the U.S. government came close to a standstill at the end of 2012 due to the “fiscal cliff,” what were the issues? Did you know?
  • A basic understanding of economics makes you a well-rounded thinker. When you read articles about economic issues, you will understand and be able to evaluate the writer’s argument. When you hear classmates, co-workers, or political candidates talking about economics, you will be able to distinguish between common sense and nonsense. You will find new ways of thinking about current events and about personal and business decisions, as well as current events and politics.

The study of economics does not dictate the answers, but it can illuminate the different choices.

National Academies Press: OpenBook

Engineering Economic Analysis Practices for Highway Investment (2012)

Chapter: chapter three - case examples.

Below is the uncorrected machine-read text of this chapter, intended to provide our own search engines and external engines with highly rich, chapter-representative searchable text of each book. Because it is UNCORRECTED material, please consider the following text as a useful but insufficient proxy for the authoritative book pages.

32 chapter three Case examples ImpaCt of CrItICal Interstate transportatIon faCIlItIes Introduction The Port Authority of New York and New Jersey (PANYNJ) is a regional public authority established by bi-state charter that operates a number of multimodal transportation facili- ties within its defined Port District. It has responsibility for major interstate transportation facilities, including six highway crossings between New York and New Jersey and transporta- tion stations and centers in both states. It operates three major metropolitan airports and two regional airports, several marine facilities, and transit lines with ferry connections to Manhattan. The PANYNJ also oversees reconstruction of the World Trade Center in Lower Manhattan (“The Port Authority . . .” n.d.; “Overview of Facilities and Services” 2010). Despite the signif- icance of its existing transportation infrastructure and resulting impacts to the movement of people and goods throughout the metropolitan region, PANYNJ before 2000 had not attempted to quantify comprehensively the economic benefits conferred by its transportation infrastructure. This case describes the first step in that quantification: the estimation of the economic ben- efits of PANYNJ’s interstate transportation facilities. Although the Port Authority’s own study considered several categories of infrastructure outlined previously, this case example focuses specifically on the six bridges and tunnels between New York and New Jersey; facilities that can be regarded as critical infra- structure in terms of the impact of highway investment on local and regional economic conditions. The data and methodology used in this effort form part of a proposed regional cost–benefit capability described here. The case is unique given the network- level significance and criticality of the transportation facilities involved. Within the framework of this synthesis, it provides an example of planning information developed at a corridor and network level. The documentary source for this critical facilities case is the economic impact study performed for the Port Authority by a consulting firm (The Economic Impact . . . 2000). Other sources relating to a specific issue regarding the Bayonne Bridge will be presented at that point later in the case example. role of economic analysis in Highway Investment Facilities The Port Authority’s transportation facilities are located in the New York–New Jersey metropolitan region as illustrated in Figure 1. The Port Authority Interstate Transportation Facili- ties (PAITF), which is the focus of this case example, is a sub- set of the facilities in Figure 1 comprising the following: • Highway Bridges and Tunnels – George Washington Bridge, Goethals Bridge, Outer- bridge Crossing, Bayonne Bridge – Lincoln Tunnel, Holland Tunnel. • Interstate Transit Links – Port Authority Trans-Hudson (known as PATH) tran- sit service – Coordination of transit service with ferry services to downtown and midtown Manhattan that are provided by other operators. • Transportation Stations and Centers – Port Authority Bus Terminal – George Washington Bridge Bus Station – Journal Square Transportation Center. Daily use of these facilities is shown in Table 7, which orga- nizes the facilities into four major corridors. This traffic repre- sents the major share of commuter and freight flows between New York and New Jersey. The PAITF are critical links within the highway, transit, and rail networks that serve the New York–New Jersey metropolitan region shown in Figure 1. These networks connect New York City, Long Island, the northern suburbs of New York, other points north, other points east of the Hudson River, the northern suburbs of New Jersey, and other points west of the Hudson River. The Midtown Cor- ridor shows substantial road traffic in the Lincoln Tunnel. This tunnel, which provides an exclusive bus lane, is a major transit corridor into midtown Manhattan. The Port Authority’s report includes a separate estimate of the benefits of this bus traffic. In addition to the PAITF, rail and transit services to midtown are provided by Amtrak, New Jersey Transit, the Metro–North Railroad, the Long Island Rail Road, New York City Transit, and private commuter bus and ferry services. Components of the Analysis Three components of economic benefit were considered in the Port Authority study of the PAITF: 1. Transportation benefits, comprising savings in travel time and VOC resulting from the existence of a PAITF facility.

33 FIGURE 1 Locations of PANYNJ transportation facilities. Source: Port Authority of New York and New Jersey, http://www.panynj.gov/about/facilities-services.html. Corridor/Facility Weekday Use Weekend Use Measure of Use Northern Corridor George Washington Bridge 151,700 149,000 Vehicles Midtown Corridor Lincoln Tunnel 62,200 57,400 Vehicles PATH Service to 33rd Street 41,300 21,600 Passenger trips Midtown Ferry Service 11,500 6,100 Passenger trips Downtown Corridor Holland Tunnel 49,700 49,500 Vehicles PATH to World Trade Center 60,400 13,400 Passenger trips Downtown Ferry Service 12,500 1,500 Passenger trips Southern Corridor Goethals Bridge 36,000 38,000 Vehicles Outerbridge Crossing 40,900 45,900 Vehicles Ba yo nne Bridge 9,700 7,000 Vehicles Source: The Economic Impact… (2000). TABLe 7 DAILY USe OF PAITF, 1999

34 2. Operating and capital impacts, the result of expendi- tures on the Interstate Facilities by the Port Authority, its tenants, and other transportation providers. These expenditures purchase goods and services from regional businesses that support the maintenance, operation, and enhancement of the facilities. The result is not only an improved level of transportation service, but also an improved economic welfare of the region resulting from direct purchases and subsequent indirect purchases owing to PAITF expenditures. 3. Competitive impacts, which result from more efficient access to, and movement within, the region served by PAITF. This benefit reflects the improved economic competitiveness and stimulation of growth owing to services provided by the Interstate Facilities in several categories; for example, commuter trips between New Jersey and New York, tourist travel, intra-regional and longer-distance trucking shipments, and direct eco- nomic development occurring around and surrounding PAITF locations. This synthesis focuses on the first of these benefits cate- gories, direct transportation benefits, and on the bridges and tunnels specifically, because these tend to be the most preva- lent for consideration in LCCAs for highway investment. methods and measures Analytic Principle A methodology was needed to address the quantification of benefits resulting from facilities of different modes, character- istics, and usages, located within an extensive metropolitan, multimodal transportation network. The principle that was adopted was that the benefits of an existing facility would be equal to the additional costs to all travelers if that facility were removed from the network. Worded more formally in the Port Authority report: The transportation benefits of a facility are defined in this [Port Authority] study as the value of increased travel costs, consist- ing of travel time and vehicle operating costs, that displaced users would incur if that facility were no longer available, and all other network facilities remained open. Source: The Economic Impact . . . 2000, p. 5. The Port Authority believed that this estimate was con- servative in the following sense: If two or more Interstate Facilities were closed down simultaneously, the overall cost impacts would likely exceed the sum of the costs of individu- ally removing each of these facilities from the network. The Port Authority also realized that highway-user costs would differ among facilities for several reasons, including wide variations in origin–destination points among respective road users, the convenience of the preferred river crossings perceived by users, the convenience and travel cost of avail- able alternate routes, and existing levels of congestion. The Port Authority’s study offered the following examples to illustrate these points. . . . closing the George Washington Bridge imposes a high increase in travel time on its users principally because alterna- tive river crossings (primarily the Holland and Lincoln Tunnels) are relatively distant and the sheer volume of present users at the George Washington Bridge would cause grave congestion prob- lems at these alternative crossings. On the other hand, closing the Holland Tunnel would lead to significantly smaller increases in travel costs because the existing traffic at the Holland Tunnel is much lower . . . and alternative facilities are both relatively near and capable of absorbing the increase in traffic. Similarly, while the Goethals Bridge and Outerbridge Crossing serve over- lapping markets and have similar traffic levels, the analysis mag- nifies the impact of the latter bridge because it does not have as many nearby alternatives as the former. Source: The Economic Impact . . . 2000, p. 5. Methodology With this guiding principle established, the calculation of benefits was organized within a methodology that entailed four basic assumptions governing the determination of needed input values. These assumptions involved value of road users’ time, value of VOC, the degree of diversion to transit, and projection of traffic volumes to year 2000, the base year of the analysis. • Value of road users’ time. Value of time was estimated based on relationship to wage rates and variations based on trip purpose. The assumed values of time were as fol- lows: working time during transportation (e.g., truck and bus drivers) is equal to the gross wage; commuting time is equal to 50% of the gross wage; and leisure time (or personal travel) is equal to 25% of the gross wage. Val- ues of the gross wage were estimated based on the aver- age wage in the vehicles’ destination county in the a.m. travel period (from origin–destination data), because the destination would be an indication of work location for commuters. Destination county was also used to estimate the wages of those in heavy-goods vehicles, factored at 100% of the county’s average wage. The value of travel time associated with each vehicle also accounted for aver- age vehicle occupancy. • Value of VOC. VOC include the costs of fuel, oil, tire wear, and vehicle maintenance, plus an allowance for the capital cost of the vehicle. A literature review was con- ducted to estimate the following composite values for the New York metropolitan area: $0.29 per mile for autos, $1.20 per mile for trucks, and $0.91 per mile for buses. • Diversion to transit. Some of the road users displaced by bridge or tunnel closure were expected to divert to mass transit. An elasticity factor was assumed based on locally available transportation alternatives at each PAITF. This elasticity of transit use to auto travel time was estimated to be 0.15 to 0.3, with the study assump- tions leaning toward the higher end of this range. For example, an elasticity of 0.25 would mean that for every 10% increase in auto travel time, transit use

35 would increase by 2.5%. This range of 0.15 to 0.3 was somewhat lower than values appearing in the literature at the time of the study (extending to 0.8). The lower values were believed to be more realistic for this par- ticular study; however, because other studies had found relatively inelastic behavior of auto travelers on trans- Hudson crossings with respect to diversion to transit. • Projected traffic volume. Available traffic data were projected to the study year (2000) to arrive at 24-hour weekday distributions, which served as a basis for assum- ing traffic volume inputs. Other data were applied to complete the estimate. For example, survey results were available to enable estimates of average vehicle occupancy on certain of these bridges and tunnels, as well as trip purpose. The Interstate Network Analysis (INA) model was used to simulate the closing of individual bridges and tunnels and the resulting “shock” impacts throughout the network. These impacts consisted of rerouting the displaced vehicles to the “best” available alternative based on their origin–destination data, and then rerunning the INA model to compute a new net- work equilibrium. The model did not assume any peak shift- ing as the result of these diversions, regardless of the level of congestion and increased travel time to the road users. More- over, the focus of the calculations was on the change in travel costs to the former users of the closed facility, not to the users of other facilities in the network. (This assumption is another indication that the estimate of transportation benefit conferred by each Interstate Facility was conservative.) The INA model then reported the net increases in travel time and distance for road users, which were converted to costs using the travel time and VOC inputs discussed earlier. The results of this analysis show that the George Washing- ton Bridge has greater benefits than the other crossings, for the reasons cited earlier: heavy travel demand and the lack of alternate crossings nearby. Results for each bridge and tunnel are also available disaggregated into three line items that respond to the imposed closure of a facility: the cost of increased travel time experienced by former users of the facil- ity who must now divert to alternate routes; the increased time for former facility users who are now diverting to transit; and the increased cost of vehicle operation by former users of the closed facility. Decision support Background Information The economic analysis described earlier provides a point of departure for more comprehensive and detailed analyses of the roles that these critical interstate transportation facilities serve at a regional and national level. As an example, the fol- lowing paragraphs frame a transportation issue that PANYNJ is now dealing with that involves significant investment needs as well as significant impacts to regional highway transporta- tion and, potentially, to national and international maritime shipping. The issue is multimodal and multijurisdictional: it involves benefit–cost applications in both a regional and a national context. The issue concerns the Bayonne Bridge, which is shown at the lower-left-hand area of Figure 1. The bridge carries a high- way link between Bayonne, New Jersey and Staten Island, New York. The body of water that it crosses, the Kill Van Kull, is the entrance westward to the Port Authority’s mari- time facilities, also shown in Figure 1. The current height of the bridge over the water (151 ft), referred to as its air draft, is becoming a limiting factor on shipping entering the port because of the increasing size of cargo ships worldwide. This growth in the dimensions of large container ships is expected to increase when the capacity expansion of the Panama Canal is completed by 2015. The Port Authority recognizes a dual set of objectives and needs regarding issues such as this air- draft constraint: to continue providing a world-class port with navigable channels and clearances that can accommodate large cargo vessels and continue to provide the landside infrastruc- ture needed to move cargo (“Next Steps to Address . . .” n.d.). USACE Air Draft Analysis In 2008, the Port Authority commissioned the New York District of the U.S. Army Corps of engineers (USACe) to study “the commercial consequences of and the national economic ben- efits that could be generated by a potential remedy of the Bay- onne Bridge’s air draft restriction” (“Next Steps to Address . . .” n.d.). The USACe approached the problem by addressing when and to what extent the Bayonne Bridge would present an obstacle to larger ships, what are the economic consequences, and would further planning and environmental analyses of pos- sible solutions be warranted. The report was conducted in the nature of a Corps reconnaissance study, rather than a feasibility study, in that it did not recommend a specific project or cost- sharing plan. However, it did provide technical and economic data responsive to the Port Authority’s planning and decision- making needs. The primary findings of this study included the following (Bayonne Bridge Air Draft Analysis Sep. 2009): • The current height of the Bayonne Bridge is and will be an obstruction to larger container vessels within a 50-year analysis horizon. • Based on preliminary estimates addressing a range of engineering solutions to the air-draft problem, all have favorable benefit–cost ratios as summarized in Table 8. • Further planning and environmental analyses by the Port Authority are warranted to identify a preferred solution to the air-draft restriction. The current Bayonne Bridge structure is a steel arch with cables suspended from the arch to support the roadbed. The

36 USACe considered the following engineering alternatives to remove the bridge air-draft restriction: • Jack the existing steel arch and roadbed to a new height providing an air draft of 215 ft. • Build a new bridge structure with an air draft of 215 ft. • Bore a tunnel under the Kill Van Kull to replace the existing bridge. • Construct an immersed tunnel under the Kill Van Kull to replace the existing bridge. The benefit–cost results for each of these alternatives are shown in Table 8. Costs were estimated using data provided by PANYNJ’s Tunnels, Bridges & Terminals Department, based on the start of detailed engineering and design in 2010. Facility operation and maintenance (O&M) costs were esti- mated for each alternative, using the 50-year analysis period with O&M costs commencing at the completion of construc- tion. Benefits were estimated according to National economic Development (NeD) guidance, discussed here. Benefits were assumed to commence at the completion of construction of each alternative as shown in Table 8, including removal of the constraining roadbed from the channel. Net present value, benefit–cost ratio, and IRR of the cost and benefit streams were computed using a discount rate of 4.625% over a 50-year analysis period. The USACe also projected 50-year forecasts on the characteristics of shipping to the Port of New York and New Jersey (PONYNJ) in the absence of alteration or replacement of the Bayonne Bridge (i.e., the No-Build option) (Bayonne Bridge Air Draft Analysis Sep. 2009, pp. 32–36, Appendix B). Federal objectives and guidelines regarding studies of water and related land/resources development are spelled out in a document prepared by the U.S. Water Resources Coun- cil (Economic and Environmental Principles . . . Mar. 1983). The federal objective in project planning involving these resources is “to contribute to national economic devel- opment consistent with protecting the Nation’s environ- ment,” and to do so in compliance with relevant federal statutes, executive orders, and other planning requirements (Economic and Environmental Principles . . . Mar. 1983, p. iv). Project plans might address problems and explore opportunities to meet this objective, including identification of project benefits that contribute to NeD. Contributions to NeD are defined as “increases in the net value of the national output of goods and services, expressed in monetary units” (p. iv). Contributions to NeD may occur within the study region, or elsewhere in the nation as the result of the proj- ect. That NeD reflects a net increase in total output implies real gains attributable to the project on a nationwide basis, not simply a transfer of benefits from one region of the country to another. Benefits of the proposed Bayonne Bridge project were analyzed in terms of the reduced costs of maritime shipping owing to economies of scale in using larger vessels. To com- pute this cost reduction, USACe formulated two future pos- sibilities: (1) the Without-Project (or No-Build) condition, in which maritime commerce entering PONYNJ would be car- ried in smaller, less economically efficient vessels that could operate with the restricted air draft of the Bayonne Bridge; and (2) the With-Project condition, in which the existing air- draft constraint is removed by bridge alteration or replacement, allowing larger, taller vessels to be added to New York-bound routes. The USACe analysis forecast the amount of freight commerce through PONYNJ over a 50-year analysis period. It also forecast changes in the worldwide shipping fleet with the addition of the larger container vessels, contrasting the fleets to be used in Conditions 1 and 2. The USACe analysis then in effect “loaded” the two fleets with the projected cargo volumes, estimated the number of trips and container-miles required for the With-Project and Without-Project assumptions, and com- puted the respective vessel operating costs in each case. The difference between these two shipping-cost totals was taken as the NeD benefit attributable to the project (Bayonne Bridge Air Draft Analysis Sep. 2009, pp. 12, 13, 32, 33). USACe dealt with a number of issues in formulating this economic benefits study (Bayonne Bridge Air Draft Analysis Sep. 2009, pp. 13–32): • The trends in several inputs to the benefits computation had to be estimated through the 50-year analysis period. Alternative Year the Im provem ent Is in Place Break-Even Year Benefit– Cost Ratio Internal Rate of Return Net Benefit, $Billions Jack Structure to 215 ft 2019 2033 3.0 10.7% $3.271 New Structure at 215 ft 2022 2039 2.1 8.4% $2.822 Bored Tunnel 2024 2042 1.9 7.7% $2.585 Immersed Tunnel 2024 2051 1.4 6.1% $1.517 Source: Bayonne Bridge Air Draft… Sep. 2009, Tables 4 and 6. TABLe 8 SUMMARY OF BeNeFIT–COST ReSULTS, USACe AIR-DRAFT STUDY

37 These trends included a forecast of commerce through PONYNJ, the characteristics of the future maritime fleet, likely patterns of fleet use on routes bound for U.S. east Coast ports, loading patterns in accommodating cargo on different types of vessels while conforming to the opera- tional needs of regularly scheduled service worldwide (i.e., ships depart ports on a schedule, whether or not fully loaded), how the vessel fleets should be deployed in the analysis to handle growth in cargo volume for the With-Project and Without-Project conditions respec- tively, and estimation of the costs of operating vessels in the With-Project and Without-Project fleets. • USACe also had to address other potential restrictions on shipping that might negate the benefits of the Bayonne Bridge project. For example, if PONYNJ harbor chan- nels were not deep enough to handle large vessels, the prospective benefits of increasing the air draft on the Bayonne Bridge might never be realized. On this par- ticular point, an earlier Harbor Navigation Study (HNS) had been performed in 1999, recommending deepening of several channels in PONYNJ; construction funding for this project was authorized by the U.S. Congress in 2000. For a number of positive reasons, USACe applied the NeD methodology used in the Harbor Navigation Study to its air-draft study. This consistency of method made it possible for the Corps to ensure that the benefits of the air-draft project were separate and distinct from the benefits of the harbor deepening work, avoiding double-counting or overstating of benefits. • Other external factors and constraints could also limit the actual benefits to be realized from the Bayonne Bridge project, along the lines suggested in the preced- ing item. For example, possible limitations in rail and highway capacity, port crane capacity, berthing space, and yard capacity could themselves limit the volume of cargo handled by PONYNJ, apart from restrictions imposed by the bridge air draft. Also note that the Bay- onne Bridge is not an obstacle to port facilities located eastward, so greater use of these port facilities could increase benefits regardless of whether or not the air- draft constraint were removed. (This is not to say that such capacity constraints actually existed. USACe was just pointing out that a valid evaluation of benefits needed to consider these other factors, which was done in a broad context in developing the findings of the air-draft study.) • A similar point related to more global constraints—the USACe further considered whether these might limit the benefits that could be realized by altering or replacing the Bayonne Bridge. A key global constraint was the existence of air-draft restrictions in other parts of the world, which might themselves constrain the heights of future maritime fleet additions. The Corps investi- gated these and found that although certain height lim- its did exist, the air draft of the Bayonne Bridge was the most constraining among those affecting 12 major ports worldwide. USACe further considered other factors that might influ- ence future decisions on the project, and conducted scenario analyses to investigate the effects of differing assumptions underlying the study. • The Corps recognized factors that were outside the scope of its study, but that could inform and affect PANYNJ’s decisions on how to proceed on this project. These included regional and local economic benefits and impacts (as compared with the national benefits com- puted in the air-draft study); the possibility that not all NeD benefits were accounted for in the study (maritime transportation cost savings tend to be used as a NeD benefit measure because they are relatively conserva- tive and easier to compute than other categories of ben- efits); and that although the study referred generally to “the Port of New York and New Jersey,” the Port com- prises a number of stakeholders to whom benefits will accrue; for example, ocean carriers, terminal operators, labor interests, land-side transportation providers, and regional consumers (Bayonne Bridge Air Draft Analysis Sep. 2009, pp. 37–38). • The Corps recognized several areas of potential uncer- tainty in the analysis, and subjected each to scenario testing in which key parameters or assumptions were varied to assess their impact on the economic results. Nine categories of scenario analyses were addressed in all, covering diverse aspects such as the projections of maritime commerce, shifts in the location of man- ufacturing in Asia and their effect on shipping to the east Coast, project cost estimates, different engineer- ing options in the height to which the bridge roadway might be raised, and delays in the start of design and construction, among others. For a given category, the scenarios comprised several repetitions of the analysis, each repetition testing a different parameter value or assumption. Results of each repetition provided infor- mation comparable to that shown in Table 8. Coming PANYNJ Analyses The USACe analysis demonstrated that the Bayonne Bridge project was justified economically from a national perspec- tive. This result opened the door for the Port Authority to con- duct its own technical and economic analyses of the project and how it might proceed. As the contact representative of the PANYNJ has pointed out, the roles of the respective eco- nomic analyses can be understood essentially as follows: the USACe analysis indicated that the project is justified at a national level, whereas the PANYNJ analysis will indicate whether the regional benefits exceed the costs. The coming PANYNJ regional analysis will examine issues not addressed in detail in the national study; for example, a more comprehen- sive assessment of highway-user benefits addressing the land- side facilities of PONYNJ (including traffic over the Bayonne Bridge during and after construction), and changes in maritime

38 air pollution emissions because of the anticipated shift in ves- sel fleet characteristics calling on PONYNJ as the result of the modified air draft. In December 2010, the Port Authority announced that its preferred engineering option for the Bayonne Bridge would be a reconstruction of the main-span roadbed and bridge approaches and ramps, to raise the roadbed as it crosses the channel through its supporting steel arch. As of March 2011, PANYNJ was proceeding to identify and select an engineer- ing consultant to provide design services for this project. resources needed and other Information Resources The PANYNJ’s study of the economic impacts of its trans- portation infrastructure has been accomplished with the assis- tance of a consulting firm working with Port Authority staff. Although USACe personnel performed the cost and benefit analysis for the Bayonne Bridge Air Draft study and developed a portion of the input data, it obtained other data from PANYNJ. Corps personnel also met with PANYNJ consultants who were performing comparable analyses on other studies, to compare trend projections and check their consistency. plannIng anD programmIng: mobIlIty anD safety projeCts Introduction This section presents the methodology now used by WSDOT for highway capital programming, currently being extended to highway system planning. WSDOT’s programming pro- cess has been in place for almost two decades, and has bene- fited from continual updating, improvement, and integration within broader statewide performance-accountability initia- tives. This case example describes work that is comprehen- sive, innovative, and unique in the thorough integration of economic thinking from the top-level guidance of enabling state legislation through detailed analysis of the estimated costs, benefits, and technical performance of project alter- natives. An extensive information infrastructure has been built to support these procedures in headquarters and region (district) offices. WSDOT’s Capital Program Development and Management Office (CPDM) provides overall guidance to this effort in its conception, implementation, and applica- tion. Although WSDOT manages programs across several modes and types of work, the processes and economic analy- ses described here apply only to the highway construction program. It would normally be more natural to explain the planning process first, followed by capital programming. However, given the history of program-development pro- cesses at WSDOT, the following description will reflect the chronological order of their implementation: highway capi- tal programming first, followed by the extension to highway system planning. role of economic analyses in Highway Investment Background In 1990, WSDOT began working on a new, performance- based capital programming process under a project sponsored by the (then Joint) Legislative Transportation Committee. It had become apparent by that time that an emerging set of policy issues at the federal and state levels would confront WSDOT and Washington’s Transportation Commission, and changes to the highway capital construction programming process would be needed. Key objectives to be met included: (1) a strong, clear connection between the programming pro- cess and the emerging policy concerns; (2) a strengthened abil- ity to highlight and evaluate key tradeoffs in funding projects; (3) a more rational, understandable basis for prioritization rooted in economic as well as engineering performance; and (4) incorporation of greater flexibility and accountability in rec- ommending projects. The study was concluded in 1991, and its recommendations were accepted by WSDOT for future imple- mentation. Since that time, the programming process has been continually refined to meet new transportation program needs, accommodate the terms of new legislative requirements and funding sources, update analytic methods and decision criteria, contribute to statewide initiatives in performance-based man- agement and accountability, and incorporate new technology. Statutory Program Guidance The Revised Code of Washington (RCW) compiles all per- manent laws of the state of Washington; Title 47 deals with public highways and transportation. RCW 47.05, Priority Programming for Highway Development, was rewritten in 1993 as the result of the capital programming study men- tioned earlier and enabled WSDOT implementation of the new programming process to be fully implemented. The new statute restructured Washington’s highway investment program, introduced new capital construction programming processes that considered least-cost and benefit–cost evalu- ations of proposed solutions to transportation problems, and responded to new policy initiatives at the state and federal levels. The law has been revised since then to be coordinated with other chapters of Title 47 (e.g., defining legislatively mandated transportation goals) and to fit within an expand- ing application of performance-based management through- out Washington state government. The declaration of purpose of RCW 47.05 is as follows, with specific reference to use of economic methods: The legislature finds that solutions to state highway deficiencies have become increasingly complex . . . Difficult investment trade-offs will be required. It is the intent of the legislature that investment of state trans- portation funds to address deficiencies on the state highway system be based on a policy of priority programming having as its basis the rational selection of projects and services according to factual need and an evaluation of life cycle costs and benefits that are system- atically scheduled to carry out defined objectives within available

39 revenue. The state must develop analytic tools to use a common methodology to measure benefits and costs for all modes. The priority programming system must ensure preservation of the existing state highway system, relieve congestion, provide mobility for people and goods, support the state’s economy, and promote environmental protection and energy conservation. . . . The priority programming system for improvements must incorporate a broad range of solutions that are identified in the statewide transportation plan as appropriate to address state highway system deficiencies, including but not limited to high- way expansion, efficiency improvements, nonmotorized trans- portation facilities, high occupancy vehicle facilities, transit facilities and services, rail facilities and services, and transpor- tation demand management programs. Source: http://apps.leg. wa.gov/rcw/default.aspx?cite=47.05.010. Legislatively mandated goals for the transportation pro- gram are as follows (RCW 47.04.280): • Economic vitality: To promote and develop transpor- tation systems that stimulate, support, and enhance the movement of people and goods to ensure a prosperous economy; • Preservation: To maintain, preserve, and extend the life and utility of prior investments in transportation systems and services; • Safety: To provide for and improve the safety and security of transportation customers and the transpor- tation system; • Mobility: To improve the predictable movement of goods and people throughout Washington state; • Environment: To enhance Washington’s quality of life through transportation investments that promote energy conservation, enhance healthy communities, and protect the environment; and • Stewardship: To continuously improve the quality, effectiveness, and efficiency of the transportation system. programming mobility projects WSDOT’s highway capital construction program is divided into two major components, Preservation (P) and Improve- ment (I). Specific types of projects are organized within pro- gram categories under Programs P and I, respectively. Both major programs employ economic analyses to assist in project ranking and selection, program development, and recommen- dation of a biennial budget. The Preservation Program gener- ally considers the criterion of lowest life-cycle cost, whereas the Improvement Program is based typically on benefit– cost considerations. Other, nonmonetary factors are also considered in final decisions on P and I projects. The P and I programs are further subdivided into subprograms that contain specific types of projects. This case example addresses one of the Improvement Program subprograms, Mobility. The Mobility subprogram includes projects addressing urban congestion, rural mobility, urban bicycle connectiv- ity, and high-occupancy vehicle (HOV) lanes. Projects are grouped in this way to enable “peer group” or “apples-to- apples” comparisons among candidates when prioritizing and selecting the best solutions to identified needs or prob- lems. each program receives an investment target from the legislature; this target anticipates monies from a number of state and federal funding sources, each with separate require- ments (“2009–2011 Scoping . . .” Aug. 2007). Recommen- dation of those high-ranking projects to be constructed within the budget target is the task of the programming process. The process encompasses the following steps (MacDonald Feb. 2004; “WSDOT Projects . . . Prioritization” 2008): • To identify a problem or need (typically based on find- ings in the Highway System Plan), based on an identi- fied performance objective or goal. • To explore possible solutions and advance the most cost-effective and least capital-intensive alternative. • To develop a project scope that—in addition to esti- mated effects on transportation system performance— takes into account potential issues in environmental impact, roadway design, and stakeholder reaction, including community acceptance. • To estimate project costs based on information in the scope and develop a basis of estimate to document all assumptions. • To estimate project benefits based on information in the scope. • To compare the benefits and costs of this project with those of its peers to determine project rank and priority. As part of the Highway System Plan updating process, WSDOT uses multiple tools in screening and evaluating proj- ect candidates. CPDM uses the Highway Segment Analysis Program as a screening tool to identify all congested highway segments on the network, complemented by other WSDOT analytic tools (e.g., to identify bottlenecks). Resulting state highway needs are consolidated with road needs identified by MPOs, RTPOs, and tribal nations. Cost-effective solutions are then developed and analyzed using traffic analysis tools to make sure the projects improve performance. Next, the Mobil- ity Project Prioritization Process (MP3) tool is used to analyze the benefits and costs of each Mobility project as affected by its engineering and performance characteristics, to prioritize and rank projects within each subprogram, and to evaluate program tradeoffs in the face of budget constraints. • Screening criteria – Candidate projects that are not listed in the Highway System Plan are ineligible for further consideration. – To meet air quality conformity requirements, candidate projects that would degrade air quality in non attainment areas are ineligible for further consideration. – Given budget limitations, candidate projects might favor near-term to mid-term needs, rather than solely long-term needs, to warrant further consideration. • Evaluation criteria – BCA (discussed in the following section). – environmental impact: wetlands, water quality and permitting, and noise; evaluated on a nonmonetary

40 basis using either responses to yes–no questions (e.g., regarding permitting requirements) or penalty points and risk-factor points for adverse environ- mental consequences. – Stakeholder response: degree of community support, views of other stakeholders, potential disruption of neighborhoods; evaluated on a nonmonetary basis using responses to yes–no questions. – Project design: projected relationship of project to, or expected impact on, matters such as land use, efficient use of existing capacity, network/system connec- tivity, use of alternative modes including bicycling and walking, and modal integration (both inter- modal and packaged multimodal solutions); evalu- ated on a nonmonetary basis using responses to yes–no questions. These criteria are weighted, with the benefit–cost criterion having the heaviest weight. The mathematical prioritization considers both economic and nonmonetary criteria. Projects closer to the ideal-best result are higher in ranking; those closer to the theoretically worst result are lower in ranking. • Analytic tool – The MP3 analytic tool and its results are described in the following section. – To focus the technical discussion of this methodol- ogy, the case example considers a particular group of Mobility projects: those that improve highway capac- ity and operational performance to provide congestion relief. mobility methods and measures Engineering Economic Methodology The BCA of WSDOT Mobility projects is conducted using the Mobility Project Prioritization Process (MPPP or MP3). MP3 is a spreadsheet workbook that evolved from model develop- ment by WSDOT through the 1990s, which was improved with additions and modifications by a consultant team in 2000. The MP3 workbook accepts inputs on the type, location, and engineering characteristics of the project; traffic forecasting data; data to estimate benefits in travel-time reductions and collision reductions; and project cost data. MP3 users may also specify changes in key parameters [e.g., discount rate, project life cycle, benefit-days per year, hourly average annual daily traffic (AADT) distribution curves] and the internal representation of speed-flow curves to allow choice between the WSDOT default speed-flow relationship and that in the Highway Capacity Manual (HCM 2000). In most of the anal- yses, the benefit of travel-time savings is computed based on the difference in vehicle-hours of travel time with and with- out the project. For intersection improvements, the benefit of travel-time savings is based on the change in overall delay comparing the build and no-build options (Dowling Associ- ates, Inc. et al. May 2000, p. 9). eeAs of project benefits are structured individually for each type of Mobility improvement (Dowling Associates, Inc. et al. May 2000, supplemented by review of the current MP3 workbook provided by WSDOT): • Mainline lane addition/access management benefits: addition of general purpose lanes, addition of truck- climbing lanes, addition of a two-way left-turn lane on two-lane highways, and modification of type of median on four- to seven-lane highways. • HOV lane benefits: adding an HOV 2+ lane to an urban multilane highway/freeway, either or both direc- tions; converting a general purpose lane of an urban multilane highway/freeway to an HOV 2+ lane, either or both directions; and conversion of an HOV 2+ lane to an HOV 3+ lane when the HOV-lane volume reaches HOV-lane capacity. • Intersection improvement benefits: originally, improve ment of existing signalized intersections based on intersection control; later allowance for improve- ment of Stop-controlled intersections; later addition of roundabouts as a new type of intersection improvement. • New interchange benefits: new interchange at a new access point. • Park-and-ride lot benefits: road user benefits result- ing from constructing a park-and-ride lot adjacent to a state highway; the workbook provides several options on type and location of the parking lot. • Safety benefits: benefits of expected accident reduc- tions owing to the highway improvement; benefits assigned to collision reductions in five categories: fatal- ity, disabling injury, evident injury, possible injury, and property damage only. Consider the example of the addition of a general purpose lane: • Input data or internal global values on the proposed lane- addition project, traffic volume and composition, traffic growth rate, and 24-hour distribution of daily traffic are used to estimate the effects on speed and travel time under the build and no-build options, in the analysis base year and the analysis future year. Standard engineering cal- culations such as those used with the Highway Capacity Manual are applied to compute volume–capacity ratios, resulting operating speeds, implied travel times, and travel-time savings resulting from the proposed project. • Benefits in each of the 24 daily hours are computed using a number of default values within MP3, which can be changed from time to time with appropriate documen- tation of source and CPDM concurrence. These values include a factor that specifies the number of days per year for which benefits are assumed (i.e., the number of days per year for which the 24-hour distribution of traf- fic applies; e.g., 260 days per year); wage rates appli- cable to drivers of general-purpose vehicles and trucks, respectively; together with a multiplicative factor identi-

41 fying the percentage of wage rate to be used in the ben- efits calculation (e.g., 50% for general vehicles, 100% for trucks), average vehicle occupancy during peak and off-peak periods, and the travel-time savings computed earlier. • Benefits are tallied for each of the 24 daily hours and expanded to annual totals for each year of the analysis period using the specified days-per-year figure discussed earlier (e.g., 260 days per year). The value of the discount rate (an MP3 global variable with default value of 4%; deviation from this figure requires WSDOT approval) is used to compute the present value of the benefits stream. • Project costs are input using data from the project scop- ing estimate or planning-level cost estimate. Construction cost inputs cover preliminary engineering, right-of- way, and construction of structures, drainage, grading, and other items. Total construction costs are reduced by the amount of cost sharing by agencies other than WSDOT. Operation and maintenance costs are input on an annual basis; a workbook calculation applies these to each year of the analysis period, and computes the pres- ent value using the present-value-of-annual-series fac- tor for the specified discount rate and length of analysis period (e.g., 4%, 20 years). The present value of total costs equals the sum of WSDOT construction costs and the present value of operation and maintenance costs. • The workbook computes the net present value (present value of benefits minus present value of costs) and the benefit–cost ratio (present value of benefits divided by present value of costs). Results of Analyses A corresponding approach is used for other types of Mobility projects addressed by the MP3 workbook. A summary of the analytic elements on each workbook tab, including the tabs (or worksheets) for the respective project types, is shown in Table 9. Results for all of these analyses are expressed as net present values and benefit–cost ratios. mobility Decision support The benefit–cost results for Mobility projects, together with results of corresponding economic analyses for other I and P subprograms, provide the economic input to project prioriti- zation that is critical to WSDOT’s development of its capital construction program and biennial budget. The recommended project rankings produced by the analytic programming procedures such as MP3 are helpful in understanding the economic value-to-cost of projects and programs, as well as their relative strengths in other, nonmonetary criteria; how- ever, they do not determine the final budget. Flexibility in the process allows WSDOT to respond to other influences such as community interest and need. Individual projects may be raised in priority and others deferred to compensate within the constrained budget. The legislature may also direct fund- ing to specific projects regardless of their computed priority (“WSDOT Projects . . . Prioritization” 2008). These results of the programming process are reviewed internally by department executives and other senior manag- ers. externally, the resulting program and budget recommen- dations are forwarded to the legislature and communicated to the appropriate executive agencies, other stakeholders, and the public. Budget recommendations are reviewed by the Washington State Legislature, including confirmation of revenue forecasts to fund the transportation programs. Separate reviews and hearings are conducted by the House and the Senate Trans- portation Committees, respectively. either committee may adjust the proposed list of projects or the amount of funding requested in any of the programs. One or both committees may file a budget bill, which proceeds through the legislative process to final passage and submittal to the governor for sig- nature. The governor may sign the bill as is, veto selected line items, or veto the entire bill, returning it to the legislature for further action. After the transportation budget is passed and signed, CPDM works with WSDOT’s Budget Services Office to communicate legislative authorizations and funded items internally to WSDOT regional managers and modal system managers, enabling final adjustments to lists of projects and related tracking-system data. Baselines are established for monitoring subsequent project delivery at the regional and headquarters levels. These baseline data are also incorporated within the legislature’s computerized tracking system and WSDOT’s Transportation executive Information System, enabling the legislature and department executives to moni- tor progress in delivering WSDOT’s transportation programs (“Building the Capital Program” Feb. 2008). programming safety projects In May 2005, AASHTO presented WSDOT with its newly established Safety Leadership Award, recognizing the depart- ment’s “proactive approach to safety”: This approach involved [a] local, corridor, and system-wide perspective. Working with other safety agencies, WSDOT adopted a strategic safety plan, called Target Zero. As an out- come, the state has had a 56% decrease in fatal and disabling crash rates since 1990 even though vehicle miles traveled over that period have increased by 35%. Source: Measures, Markers, and Mileposts: The Gray Notebook, Quarter ending June 30, 2005, p. 52. Washington State has continued to apply its management, planning, engineering, data collection, and analytic resources to identify and apply cost-effective measures that reduce the societal costs of fatal and disabling crashes. The approach is holistic in that a number of Washington’s highway programs and subprograms have measurable safety-related objectives. These objectives consider historical experience; for exam- ple, highway locations/sections that have a serious accident

42 Worksheet Description Required Inputs/Actions Optional Inputs Notes/Comments Software Notes Provides software’s purpose, structure, color coding scheme. Describes each of the worksheets. None None None Project Description Project description Project description, including route, posted speed, title, beginning and ending mileposts, no build and build num ber of lanes, and terrain None The default population density is taken from the Global Variables worksheet. Posted speeds are rounded to 50, 60, or 70 mp h. Global Variables Benefit–cost analysis assum ptions and default values that are used throughout the workbook. Discount rate ( i ), project life cycle ( n ), benefit days per year, select or define ADT 24- h distribution curve, identify start and end of a.m . and p.m . peak periods, value of tim e and operating costs, population density (urban or rural) Project-specific peak and/or off-peak AVOs. Can provide ratio of benefits to new users (default assumes economic “rule of half”) Defaults should be used unless there is a co mp elling reason to do otherwise. Any m odifications to the default values need to be docum ented. 24-Hour Volume Distribution Chart Graphically displays the selected Year 1 directional and total volume distribution by hour of the day Select or define the ADT 24-h distribution curve in the Global Variables worksheet. The selected curve will automatically be displayed in the 24 Hour Volume Distribution chart None Graph only displays the selected Year 1 curve. Estimate and B-C Ratio Cost estimates for preliminary engineering, environmental retrofit, right-of-way, construction, operation & maintenance. Incorporates present value of user benefits for each particular im provem ent. Estimates the benefit/cost ratio. Quantities needed for cost calculations, non-WSDOT cost share, and operation & maintenance costs, or total WSDOT present value costs (PVc) User has the option of entering general cost per m ile estimates, or a resultant to tal WSDOT present value cost (PVc) estim ated outside of the worksheet. Can use general cost per mile calculations or detailed cost calculations Output from this worksheet is used as inputs to TOPSIS to pr io ritize highway mobility projects. 4-Step M odel Benefits Estim ates annual 24-h user benefits based on output from an accepted 4-step m odel. Model description, truck percent, peak period AVOs, and 24-h vehicle-hours traveled on state facilities 24-h vehicle-hours traveled on entire system , not just state system. Can estim ate user benefits for entire system if data are provided, but only benefits for state system users will be incorporated into overall project B/C rat io. Two-Way Left-Turn Lane (TWLTL) and Multilane Acces s Management Benefits Estim ates annual 24-h user benefits for converting a 2-lane undivided facility to a 3-lane TWLTL facility (Harwood/St. John method), or for median treatm ents and/or access spacing changes for 4–7 lane facilities ( NCHRP 395 method). Peak direction of selected ADT hourly distribution curve, median type, average access spacing, access control class, daily and peak hour traffic data, and truck % Peak and nonpeak turns per access, if evaluating benefits using the NCHRP 395 meth od. Uses ADT hourly distribution curve selected in Global Variables to estimate peak and off-peak percents and to convert working peak hour user benefits to 24-h benefits. General Purpose Lane Benefits Estim ates annual 24-h user benefits for adding a general purpose lane. Facilities that can be analyzed include: a 2- lane highway, an arterial, a rural/sm all urban freeway, or a mu ltilane highway or freeway. No build and build posted speeds, direction(s) of added lane, ADT and K factor or working peak hour volum es, truck percent, grade and length of grade, volume growth rate, and roadway type ADT and K factor or working peak hour volume is required, but either can be input. Can input data for one or two directions. Benefits are estimated by each hour of the day for the selected direction(s) of the facility. Climbing Lane Benefits Estimates the annual 24-h user benefits for adding a truck clim bing lane to a 2-lane highway or to an arterial. Sam e as above Sam e as above This worksheet has not been updated to look up values from the WSDOT speed-flow curve worksheet. WSDOT curves are em bedded in worksheet. TABLe 9 MP3 WORKSHeeT DeSCRIPTIONS

43 role of economic analysis in Highway safety Investment The computation of the societal costs of accidents (or the benefits of avoiding these costs) is based on the following (Median Treatment Study . . . Mar. 2002): • Identification of the societal costs of different severities of accident: cost per fatal collision, cost per disabling (or serious) injury collision, cost per evident injury col- lision, cost per possible injury collision, and cost per property-damage-only collision. • Identification of the frequency of occurrence of each cat- egory of accident severity, before and after a particular history—as well as proactive analyses of highway character- istics and traffic volumes and behaviors that point to a poten- tial for accidents in the future (“Safety Management System” Oct. 2009). WSDOT’s highway system Preservation (P), Improvement (I), and Maintenance (M) programs all play a role in promoting highway safety. However, this case exam- ple will focus specifically on projects included in the Safety improvement (I2) subprogram. Although a number of state DOTs use economic dollar values in analyzing accident costs and conduct safety-related benefit–cost studies, WSDOT’s approach is unique in the way it has organized the leadership of statewide highway safety initiatives, including coordina- tion with other agencies and stakeholders. Worksheet Description Required Inputs/Actions Optional Inputs Notes/Comments Intersection Benefits Estimates the annual 24-h user benefits for improving an existing intersection No build and build total approach volumes, number of lanes, average intersection delays, and in tersectio n v/c ratios, existing approach volum es by hour for 24-h, and build scenari o percent reduction by approach Most recent counts of hourly approach volumes that can be converted to existing hourly approach volumes Benefits are estimated by each hour of the day. Since Year 20 VHT can be higher than Year 1 VHT, there is a potential for negative benefits. When negative benefits are estim ated, they are assum ed to be zero benefits. New Interchange Benefits Estimates the annual 24-h user benefits for adding a new interchange to an existing facility Year 1 and Year 20 working peak hour volumes, distances and speeds or travel tim es for no build and build or ig in– destination (O-D) pa th s Model travel times can be input for specific O-D paths instead of being calculated based on distances and speeds. Working peak hour user benefits are converted to 24-h benefits using ADT hourly distribution curve selected in Global Variables. HOV Lane Benefits Estimates the directional annual 24-h user benefits for addi ng an HOV lane Directional num ber of lanes with and without project, ADT or directional working peak hour volum es, HOV and GP growth rates, truck percentages, and traffic composition Can select the HCM 2000 speed-flow curve instead of using the WSDOT default curves. Can change default GP/HOV capacities per lane, but mu st document. Benefits are estimated by each hour of the day for the selected direction(s) of the facility. Worksheet assu me s that HOV lane can be used by GP traffic outside of the peak period. Park & Ride Lot Benefits Estimates the bi-directional annual 24-h user benefits for constructing a park & ride lot. Nu mb er of parking spaces, percent of lo t capacity used, various destination data, user distribution (t ransit riders/carpoolers), and AVOs None 24-h benefits are assum ed to be equal to working peak hour or peak period benefits. Safety Benefits Estimates the annual 24-h user benefits of im proving the safety of a facility. Selection of safety im provem ents, identification of the num ber of accidents by type of accident None None WSDOT Default Curves Contains WSDOT default speed-flow curves for 50, 60, and 70 mph facilities. Speeds are dependent on v/c ratio and the number of lanes. HOV lane speeds are dependent upon volumes. None None The lowest allowed congested speed for general purpose lane speeds is 15.2 mph (for v/c ± 1.2). Allowable HOV lane speeds are 55 mph at free-flow down to 40 mph at capacity. HOV lane speeds are solely dependent on lane volumes and an assumed capacity HCM 2000 Curves Contains the HCM 2000 speed-flow curves for freeways. Speeds are dependent on free-flow speeds, length of segment, and v/c ratio. Posted speed and length of section must be provided in the Project Description worksheet. These values are used to estimate speed-flow relationship. None Freeway speeds for GP and HOV lanes can range from free-flow speeds down to about 12 mph at a v/c of 2.0. Source: WSDOT MP3 workbook, “Software Notes” tab (2009). TABLe 9 (continued)

44 safety action (e.g., a safety project, enforcement activ- ity, or educational campaign). • Computation of benefits in terms of the reduction in accident societal costs resulting from the safety action (whether a reduction in accident frequency, accident severity, or both), comparing the “before” and “after” cases with the yearly benefits discounted through an analysis period. • Computation of costs of performing the safety action (typically construction plus maintenance) with the annual costs discounted through the analysis period. • Computation of the benefit–cost ratio, using the dis- counted values. Although the B/C ratio is computationally straightforward, predicting accident frequency and severity that result from a safety investment can be difficult. Technical studies such as those described here provide a basis for estimation. Similarly, valuing the societal costs of an accident involves a number of assumptions; cost- and benefit-related issues and a synthesis of state DOT practices are discussed by Hanley (2004). In its safety analyses, WSDOT uses societal costs recommended by FHWA (2007–2026 Highway System Plan . . . Dec. 2007). Legislative Guidance and Agency Goals WSDOT’s highway-safety approach responds to the provi- sions of the federal SAFeTeA-LU legislation (P.L. 109-59, Aug. 10, 2005). SAFeTeA-LU establishes and funds the Highway Safety Improvement Program as a core program, giv- ing states flexibility to address their most critical safety needs with a focus on demonstrating performance. It calls for states to develop Strategic Highway Safety Plans (SHSPs), approved by the governor or a responsible state agency, to identify safety needs and opportunities, propose ways to address them through prioritized actions, and evaluate the quality of data. To conform to the provisions of SAFeTeA-LU, the SHSP is developed in consultation with others involved in high- way safety. It specifies performance-based goals for meet- ing highway safety needs in both the infrastructural and the driver behavioral categories on all public roads, proposes ways to assess resulting improvement in safety performance, and applies these lessons to prioritizing future safety actions (SAFeTeA-LU Aug. 10, 2005). WSDOT’s SHSP is embodied in the Target Zero document mentioned earlier, currently updated to 2010 [(Target Zero) Washington State’s Strategic Highway Safety Plan . . . Aug. 27, 2010]. This strategic safety plan sets the important aspirational goal of zero traffic deaths and serious injuries on Washington State’s roads by 2030. Consultation in developing this SHSP has included a number of state agencies: WSDOT; State Patrol; Departments of Health, Licensing, and Social and Health Services; Washington Traffic Safety Commission; Washington Transportation Commission and a host of others; several federal agencies; tribal nations and organizations; private and nonprofit groups; and community, local, and regional agencies and organizations. The plan encompasses the “four es” commonly associated with highway safety programs: engineering, education, emergency services, and enforcement. Key elements of Target Zero are incorporated within WSDOT’s 20-year Highway System Plan. The SHSP indicates that fatal highway accidents have declined in Washington State from a rate of 4.91 deaths per 100 million vehicle-miles traveled (MVMT) in 1966 to 0.94 per 100 MVMT in 2008, the state’s lowest traffic fatality rate on record and below the 1.27 per 100 MVMT national rate computed by NHTSA (Target Zero, p. 7). Several likely reasons for this decline in fatal crashes are cited, including decreased levels of driving resulting from escalating gaso- line prices and the economic recession in 2008; investments in cost-effective, performance-enhancing safety projects; improvements in roadway engineering, specific roadside safety features (discussed in greater detail later), vehicle design, and safety equipment; and the beneficial effects of safety education, tougher impaired-driver and seat-belt-use laws, faster emergency response, and law enforcement. Not- withstanding these improvements, challenges to meeting the Target Zero goals remain. For example, motorcycle deaths are increasing, countering the otherwise favorable motorist fatality trend. Although impaired-driver-related fatalities are decreasing, they are not dropping fast enough to meet the 2030 zero-level target. WSDOT has adjusted its proposed safety countermeasures to address these issues. Target Zero organizes the factors involved in traffic fatali- ties, related safety analyses, and resulting recommendations within four priority levels. For the 2010 update, these priority levels are based on recorded percentages of total highway fatal- ities during 2006–2008, as follows (Target Zero, pp. 11–14): • Priority One consists of factors implicated in 40% or more of traffic fatalities between 2006 and 2008. It includes accidents involving alcohol- or drug-impaired drivers, speeding, and run-off-the-road crashes. each of these factors was identified as a contributing circum- stance in accidents accounting for 40% or more of total highway fatalities. (Author’s note: in structuring these priority levels, the number of fatalities, not the number of fatal crashes, is used.) • Priority Two consists of factors implicated in 21% to 39% of traffic fatalities in 2006–2008. It includes acci- dents involving young drivers (ages 16–20 and 21–25), unrestrained passenger vehicle occupants, distracted drivers, and accidents at intersections. • Priority Three consists of factors implicated in 11% to 20% of traffic fatalities in 2006–2008. It includes acci- dents involving unlicensed drivers; opposite-direction, multi-vehicle collisions; motorcyclists; pedestrians; and heavy trucks. • Priority Four consists of factors implicated in less than 10% of traffic fatalities in 2006–2008. It includes accidents involving older drivers, drowsy drivers, nonmotorized cyclists, road work zones, wildlife, vehicle–train collisions, school buses, and aggressive drivers.

45 Target Zero notes that many fatalities are associated with more than one of these factors. These traffic deaths are there- fore represented more than once in the fatality data associated with the four priority levels. Technical and Organizational Approach WSDOT, like several other state DOTs, has found that a partic- ularly cost-effective approach to reducing fatal and disabling- injury accidents is to invest in low-cost, systematic safety improvements. WSDOT has focused on centerline rumble strips and cable median barriers on its mainline state high- ways as successful ways to manage vehicular departures from the road. Other cost-effective, performance-enhancing safety measures include improvements in (or greater use of) the fol- lowing: pavement markings (including wider markings, chev- rons, and route decals or “horizontal signing”), directional signage, fluorescent yellow sign sheeting (e.g., on curve- warning signs), addition of left-turn lanes, active-warning sys- tems (e.g., for “crossing traffic ahead” and advanced-warning “end-of-green” flashers), roadway lighting, shoulder and edge- line rumble strips, access management (e.g., raised medi- ans), speed-feedback signs, vehicle recovery areas, guardrail end treatments, roadside or guardrail delineators, and features at intersections (e.g., improved vehicular and pedestrian traffic signals, transverse rumble strips, improved signage, and round- abouts). Several state DOT presentations on these types of traf- fic engineering countermeasures were given at a traffic safety summit (“everyOne Counts” Feb. 2009). WSDOT’s organizational approach to highway safety improvement differs from models used in some other DOTs. In lieu of a designated safety office or safety engineer, WSDOT organized a Highway Safety Issues Group (HSIG) in the 1990s. Co-chaired by the heads of traffic operations and highway design, the HSIG core membership consists of representatives of WSDOT planning, program management, traffic operations, WSDOT regional traffic and design engineers, and the FHWA division office. By its nature, it promotes a team approach and brings multidisciplinary expertise to safety issues. The HSIG undertakes a number of activities, among them identifying areas of potential safety improvement and coordinating the development of safety policies and initiatives on behalf of the department. It may undertake studies such as safety BCAs, recommend applications of departmental safety resources, and review proposed actions submitted by WSDOT management. It acts as a champion for safety. It also can interact effectively with outside groups through the Washington Traffic Safety Commission (WTSC) (Mercer Consulting Group June 2007, pp. 6–7; State of Alaska . . . Sep. 2007, p. e-15). safety program methods and measures WSDOT’s assignment of Priority One to run-off-the-road crashes and its emphasis on centerline rumble strips and cable median barriers as technically and economically feasible solutions resulted from nationwide data and analyses that were conducted in the 1990s and early 2000s. A key influ- ence on WSDOT’s thinking was a study by the Insurance Institute for Highway Safety, or IIHS (Persaud et al. 2003). The IIHS report compiled available data and research find- ings from several sources, including FHWA, NHTSA, state DOTs, and academic and consultant researchers, all within the 1990s–early 2000s time frame. These research results collectively indicated the following (Persaud et al. 2003, pp. 1–3): • Although urban areas experience the highest rates of motor vehicle accidents overall, fatal accidents are more likely to occur in rural areas (2.3 fatal crashes per 100 MVMT on rural highways versus 1.0 fatal crash per 100 MVMT on urban highways nationally). • Reasons for the higher average rate of severe accidents on rural roads include generally higher traffic speeds, lower seat belt use, longer response times for emergency medical assistance, and road design characteristics, particularly on rural two-lane roads. • Nationally, rural two-lane roads account for approxi- mately 90% of all fatal crashes on rural highways. The characteristically undivided configuration of two-lane highways, and the absence of wide medians or centerline barriers to physically separate opposing-traffic flows, are factors in vehicles crossing the centerline. • The result of vehicles departing from their correct direc- tional lanes can be head-on collisions or the sideswiping of vehicles traveling in the opposite direction. Although these collisions are not the result of a single cause, fac- tors typically cited by police include failure to keep in the proper lane, driver inattention, driver fatigue, and speeding. • Roadway widening and installation of centerline barri- ers are possible highway engineering solutions to reduce opposing-traffic collisions; however, they are expensive and therefore tend to be limited to specific, high-priority locations. Such spot-location fixes do not solve the more general problem of opposing-traffic collisions that can occur virtually anywhere along the length of a two-lane, undivided highway. • A more economical and practical potential solution is the installation of centerline rumble strips along the length of undivided two-lane highways. By providing an audible vibration under vehicles encroaching on the centerline, rumble strips can alert inattentive, fatigued, distracted, or speeding drivers that they are drifting into the opposite lane. • Rumble strips had already proven themselves on the right-hand shoulders of limited access highways in reducing run-off-the-road-to-the-right incidents, which did not involve collisions with opposing traffic. How- ever, at the time of the IIHS study (2003), there was relatively little research or field experience on how these rumble strips would perform on the centerlines of two-lane rural highways. The limited informa- tion that was available, however, comprising simple before–after comparisons of crash rates in studies

46 by two state DOTs, indicated that centerline rumble strips did reduce the rates of both head-on collisions and opposing-direction sideswipes. • The purpose of the IIHS study was to update these findings on the value of centerline rumble strips in improving rural highway safety. It did this by expand- ing the available data to a larger pool of state DOT experience, and refining the analysis of crash reduc- tions resulting from centerline rumble strips to cor- rect for certain mathematical algorithms and biases in earlier works. • The results of the 2003 IIHS study indicated that center- line rumble strips did indeed result in significant crash reductions on two-lane rural highways. All injury crashes combined (i.e., disabling injury, evident injury, and possible injury) were reduced by an average of 15%, or a range of 5% to 25% at the 95% confidence inter- val. Head-on (frontal) crashes and opposing-direction sideswipe crashes were reduced by an average 25% (5% to 45% at a 95% confidence interval). The study concluded: In light of their effectiveness and relatively low installation costs, consideration should be given to installing centerline rumble strips more widely on rural two-lane roads to reduce the risk of frontal and opposing-direction sideswipe crashes. Source: Persaud et al. 2003. The evaluation of candidate safety project sites entails a technical diagnosis of problems and potential solutions, plus a BCA to assist in prioritization. safety program Decision support Decision-Making Approach The objective of this study is to identify cost-effective solu- tions that yield a high rate of return in terms of reducing fatal and serious (or disabling) injury crashes. For a valid analy- sis, however, the locations, frequencies, and circumstances of fatal and serious-injury accidents must be known. WSDOT relies on a GIS-based safety management reporting system, supported by descriptive accident data provided by the State Patrol, which enables WSDOT managers to identify where serious safety problems exist, what factors are influenc- ing crashes (particularly those of high severity), and what options might provide the best solution. (WSDOT’s Trans- portation Data Office heads a Collision Report Commit- tee that, with the cooperation of the State Patrol, provides for uniform accident reporting across the state.) The GIS- based graphical displays are packed with information that assists highway and traffic engineers in diagnosing crash locations, clusters, and situations. The highway route and the crash-location symbols employ color coding to indi- cate crash severity, density of clustering, and locations of significant Priority One events. each accident indication can be expanded to reveal detailed text descriptions of all crashes that have occurred at that location within the speci- fied time frame (which can be multi-year), based on the aforementioned State Patrol reports. Based on these data, WSDOT can pursue cost-effective solutions that provide the “biggest bang for the buck” in addressing the targeted safety goal. As an illustration for this case example, WSDOT’s analysis shows that many fatal accidents are caused by head-on collisions on undivided highways. The GIS reporting system allows WSDOT to pinpoint those highway locations having the greatest con- centration of these crashes or of vehicles leaving the road after crossing the centerline and opposing lanes. In lieu of relatively expensive centerline barriers, WSDOT has pur- sued more economical centerline rumble strips. The BCA described earlier allows WSDOT to identify high-priority segments where the installation of centerline rumble strips is recommended. It is not unusual for B/C ratios in these seg- ments to exceed 100 to 1. Legislative Review and Approval This methodology is the foundation of WSDOT’s safety pro- gram budget recommendations. The recommendations are submitted to the legislature as part of the transportation bud- get package. The legislature reviews these recommendations and proposed funding levels, and may make adjustments as described earlier in the section on Mobility before sending the approved budget to the governor for signature. Follow-Up Studies WSDOT has followed up on this benefit/cost-based prioriti- zation process to determine whether the safety performance results for centerline rumble strips has been effective. (One could also consider economic performance to be reflected in the before–after analysis of crash statistics, because changes in the frequencies of different accident severities underlay the benefit–cost calculation.) The results of this follow-up study could then inform any updates needed in WSDOT’s highway design guidance for centerline rumble strips. Find- ings and conclusions of this study were as follows (Olson et al. Mar. 2011, pp. ix–x): • The collisions of primary concern when installing cen- terline rumble strips are crashes with opposing traffic, either frontal (head-on) or sideswipes. The observed before–after results were a 44.6% reduction in All Injury Severities and a 48.6% reduction in Fatal & Serious (Disabling) Injury collisions. • In this study, this positive performance result held for all ranges of posted speed limits. No particular speed limit (or range of limits) detracted from the reduction in cross-centerline collisions. • This positive performance result held for all contributing causes to crashes except one: excess speed. An 18.5%

47 increase in Fatal & Serious Injury crashes occurred when speeding was a contributing cause. For all other contrib- uting causes, rates of both Fatal & Serious Injury crashes and All Injury Severities crashes declined following the installation of centerline rumble strips. • With respect to horizontal alignment: Cross-centerline collisions decreased by 59.0% on tangent sections and by 26.8% on curves after installing centerline rumble strips. On the curved sections that were studied, the Fatal & Serious Injury crashes that did occur were pri- marily the result of excess speed or to drivers impaired by alcohol or drugs. Also, there were differences in the resulting accident rates depending on whether the cross-centerline collisions occurred on the inside or the outside of the highway curve. • Centerline rumble strips were not anticipated to reduce the collision rates for run-off-the-road-to-the-right events, but they did: a 6.9% decline in All Injury Sever- ities crashes and a 19.5% reduction in Fatal & Serious Injury crashes. Although the research team found this result interesting, further investigation as to why this result occurred and how to explain it was judged to be beyond the scope of that study. • Conclusions: Centerline rumble strips “are an effective, low-cost, low-maintenance countermeasure that sig- nificantly reduces the frequency of collisions, regard- less of lane/shoulder width, posted speed limit, or any of the other geometric conditions examined.” To fur- ther the applications of this successful countermeasure, WSDOT planned to conduct a further study of noise aspects to determine where centerline rumble strips could be installed acceptably in residential areas. Based on the findings of this study, the research team rec- ommended that (1) WSDOT maintain its current guidance on reducing cross-centerline collisions; (2) WSDOT continue installing centerline rumble strips conforming to this guid- ance; and (3) from the analytic results, future priority might be given to locations with AADT less than 8,000, combined (one-directional) lane plus shoulder widths of 12 to 17 ft, and posted speeds of 45 to 55 mph (Olson et al. 2011). extension to Highway system planning Strategic View Reducing congestion is critical to Washington State’s people, economy, environment, and quality of life. “Moving Wash- ington” has been formulated as a strategic initiative compris- ing actions in three broad areas, all of which are needed to improve mobility in major transportation corridors (“Conges- tion” and “Moving Washington . . .” 2010). WSDOT execu- tives issue guidance to the planning process in terms of these focus areas: • Managing demand entails commuter travel options that promote greater efficiency by reducing the need to drive, particularly to drive alone. There are many possibili- ties, such as access to convenient bus service, carpool- ing and vanpooling, telecommuting, and flextime. Other measures include real-time traffic information displayed on variable message signs, which can influence traffic demand to shift to less congested routes. • Operating the highway system more efficiently by improving the functioning of existing roads. This approach includes measures that smooth traffic flow and remove impediments to flow more efficiently, as in responding to accidents. • Adding capacity strategically through informed invest- ment choices by focusing on the worst bottleneck loca- tions. WSDOT notes that such an approach can improve traffic flow on longer segments of highway while remain- ing within budget constraints. These strategies are part of the process incorporated in the production of the Highway System Plan. Identifying the most cost-effective options within these strategies and pro- ducing a balanced approach to congestion reduction require additional considerations before BCAs are addressed. The WSDOT office of CPDM introduces these additional con- siderations as screening criteria and by structuring a tiered, incremental approach to defining candidate solutions for fur- ther evaluation in the planning process. Screening and Structuring Potential Solutions The screening process recognizes that there is insufficient annual funding to achieve free-flow conditions on highways statewide. The goal is therefore to achieve maximum through- put on congested state highways: approximately 2,000 vehicles per hour, at speeds of 42–51 mph, or about 70% to 85% of the posted speed. At speeds below this threshold, the throughput decreases and the highway no longer operates efficiently. A key screen used by WSDOT for assessing mainline high- way congestion is to identify locations where peak-hour speed is less than 70% of the posted limit. This is the pri- mary criterion; others, related to bottlenecks, chokepoints, and congested corridors, are described in WSDOT’s High- way System Plan (2007–2026 Highway System Plan . . . Dec. 2007). Needs identification is accomplished in coor- dination with the appropriate MPOs or RTPOs. Proposed projects that meet these criteria are advanced to the next step in the planning process. Those that do not yet meet these screening criteria are held in the Highway System Plan database for future consideration should traffic condi- tions change on these segments or locations. Another mechanism used by WSDOT to guide project development toward effective and efficient solutions is to apply a tiered, incremental approach in defining projects. In this way, solutions that do not entail large capital expendi- tures are investigated first; and, new projects build on the improvements accomplished by previous projects, avoiding

48 wasted effort. The project tiers are at three levels (2007–2026 Highway System Plan . . . Dec. 2007, p. 70): • Tier I—low-cost projects with high return on capital investment and short delivery schedules; for example, incident management, ITS, access management, ramp modifications, turn lanes, and intersection improvements. • Tier II—moderate- to higher-cost improvements that reduce congestion on both highways and affected local roads; for example, improvements to parallel corri- dors (including local roads), auxiliary lanes, and direct- access ramps. • Tier III—highest-cost projects that yield corridor-wide benefits; for example, commuter rail, HOV/HOT lanes, additional general-purpose lanes, and interchange modifications. The incremental aspect of WSDOT’s planning process means that proposed mobility solutions in Tier I must be evaluated (unless they already exist on the highway segment under study) before Tier II solutions can be recommended. Proposed mobility solutions in Tier I and Tier II must be eval- uated (unless they already exist on the highway segment under study) before Tier III solutions can be recommended. evalua- tion of tiered solutions at this step entails an analysis of traffic impacts and performance improvement over 10 or 20 years. Further Evaluations for Inclusion in System Plan Once solutions at the appropriate tiers have been identified as candidates they are subjected to a BCA using the MP3 tool. Solutions with favorable benefit–cost results receive further review under additional criteria; for example, impact on cur- rent and future needs projections, the degree of improvement in traffic throughput, and the estimated number of years that the solution will last (in terms of throughput speed meet- ing or exceeding 70% of posted speed). Proposed solutions, refinements of concepts, and the BCA are conducted in coop- eration with cognizant MPOs and RTPOs. Those projects judged most favorable are entered in the Highway System Plan database and forwarded to headquarters executives for review and approval. Projects that are judged as not yet meet- ing criteria for selection are held in the Highway System Plan database for further future analysis (“2011–2030 Highway System Plan . . .” n.d.). Analytic Tools The MP3 workbook that was described for project program- ming is also used to evaluate Mobility solution benefits at the planning stage. Because projects have not yet been scoped, however, prepared cost estimates are not available. WSDOT has therefore developed a Planning Level Cost estimation tool to estimate costs for projects still at a conceptual level of development. It is based on historical unit price data for key highway construction cost factors, accounting for regional variations and differences in land use and development den- sity within a region. Input data describe the project in terms of characteristics and features of its right-of-way, mainline roadway, intersections and interchanges, crossroads, bridges, retaining walls, noise walls, wetlands, ITS features, and other items. Unit prices are applied to the quantity estimates for these items; assigned prices also account for regional location (Central Puget Sound, Vancouver, Spokane, other parts of the state) and density of local development (rural, suburban, urban, dense urban). Adjustments can be included for preliminary engineering, mobilization, construction engi- neering, traffic control, and other implementation items, as well as a separate adjustment for uncertainty (Murshed and McCorkhill 2008). resources needed and other Information The MP3 workbook and the Planning Level Cost estima- tion tool are the primary analytic tools for the BCA at the planning stage. The MP3 workbook and project scoping estimates provide benefit–cost data for project programming. IDAS (ITS Deployment Analysis System) software is used for ITS cost and benefit estimates. WSDOT also applies a number of other software packages for different types of traf- fic analyses depending on the complexity of the proposed solution (“Requirements for Proposed . . .” n.d.). WSDOT staff is conversant with economic methods, and apply the information and tools discussed throughout this summary for long-range and biennial planning updates, capi- tal programming, and budget development. The department makes use of academic and consulting experts for tasks such as research, business-process renewal, model/system devel- opment, and implementation assistance. For the most part, however, the department assumes responsibility for using these products once completed. brIDge projeCt programmIng anD permIttIng Introduction This case describes the methodology applied by Caltrans for bridge project programming, with significant influence on deci- sions exerted by permitting requirements. Caltrans applies the Pontis™ bridge management system (BMS) for conventional analyses of bridge preservation and mobility improvement, and for decision support in project prioritization. However, a number of critical, risk-related bridge needs are not addressed by a BMS and must be analyzed separately. Moreover, bridge projects in California are potentially subject to permitting requirements or right-of-way negotiations that, experience has shown, can extend several years beyond the time needed for project plan development. The Caltrans Bridge Manage- ment Office has therefore developed a unique and innovative

49 approach to evaluating bridge projects for inclusion in its State Highway Operation and Protection Program (SHOPP). This procedure entails the use of utility theory to capture the benefits of reducing risks of degraded bridge performance regarding scour, seismic events, and bridge-railing safety, in addition to benefits associated with meeting the preserva- tion and mobility needs. This computed value of utility is applied as the measure of benefit in a “benefit–cost analysis” (or, perhaps more accurately, a cost-effectiveness analysis structured as a B/C ratio). Cost-effectiveness is not, how- ever, the only decision variable to be considered. The time to obtain permit approval for these bridge projects, particu- larly in coastal regions and certain other situations, means that the programming decision must consider those projects that realistically can be expected to be ready for construction within a manageable time period. The following descriptions describe Caltrans’ analytic procedures for programming of bridge needs, and use of these results in decisions on bridge project recommendations. role of economic analysis in Highway Investment Background With an inventory of just under 13,000 state highway bridges and with bridge needs exceeding annual funding, Caltrans looks to make informed decisions in selecting the “best” projects for its bridge program. The California SHOPP identifies bridge preservation needs in five areas: (1) reha- bilitation and replacement owing to deterioration of bridge elements, (2) scour risk reduction, (3) seismic risk reduction, (4) bridge rail upgrade (a safety matter), and (5) mobility upgrades (raising and strengthening structures to accom- modate updated traffic volumes and vehicle characteristics). SHOPP lists funding commitments to selected projects through a 4-year programming period. California state law also requires a 10-year SHOPP plan that identifies uncon- strained needs across all transportation assets. Although BMS analyses, which include economic as well as technical modeling, can address needs for preservation (rehabilitation or replacement) owing to condition-based deterioration of bridge elements and for mobility upgrades, they do not deal effectively with risk-related problems: seismic, scour, and bridge-rail safety. These risk-based needs, which account for about 40% of the total SHOPP bridge-related amount, require different analytic procedures. Caltrans has turned to multi-objective utility theory to represent the benefits of addressing the five categories of bridge needs, with initial application of the procedure to the 2008 SHOPP develop- ment (Johnson 2008). Multi-Objective Utility Model A dimensionless, multi-objective, zero-to-one utility func- tion represents the contributions of several factors relevant to programming decisions. Moreover, the factors can be weighted to reflect their relative importance. The general utility relationship is given in eq. 1 (Johnson 2008). U a b X a b X a b X a b X a b X a b t i i i= = + + + + Σ 1 1 1 2 2 2 3 3 3 4 4 4 5 5X5 1( ) where: Ut = total project utility, zero to one; S = sum for all i = 1 to 5; ai = indicator that attribute i is addressed (1 = yes, 0 = no), i = 1 to 5 denoting each category of bridge needs; bi = weighting factor for attribute i; sum of all weighting factors = 1.0; Xi = value function of attribute i contributing to the utility function, where: X1 = value function for bridge rehabilitation or replacement; X2 = value function for scour risk mitigation; X3 = value function for bridge rail upgrade; X4 = value function for seismic risk mitigation; and X5 = value function for bridge mobility improve- ment (strengthening and raising clearances). Example for Scour The individual value functions Xi are themselves relation- ships containing dependent and independent variables, coef- ficients, and functions. For example, in terms of the National Bridge Inventory (NBI) rating items, the scour-related con- tribution to utility (i.e., the value function X2) is formulated using the NBI scour item (Item 113), the average daily traffic (ADT, Item 029), and detour length (DL, Item 019) (Record- ing and Coding Guide . . . Dec. 1995). Ratings of condition within the NBI are assigned on a 0 to 9 scale, where 9 denotes “undamaged” or “not subject to risk,” 3 denotes “critical,” and 0 denotes “bridge failed, out of service.” As an example, consider the scour value function X2, with a form expressed in eq. 2. This function is graphed in Figure 2 versus the NBI scour rating code SC, with values of traffic ADT and detour length DL held constant. The value-function results are inter- preted as follows (Johnson 2008, pp. 191–192): • When SC = 8, the bridge foundation is “stable” and the scour risk is essentially zero. A project that addresses scour would therefore provide no real benefit in terms of scour risk mitigation. (An NBI rating of 9 for this item would denote a bridge foundation on dry land, well above flood water elevation, and is not represented in the value function.) • As the scour risk increases (i.e., as SC moves toward the “critical” threshold where the scour rating would equal 3), the scour value function likewise increases and at SC = 3 it exceeds 0.75. Projects that mitigate scour risk now are in a range to contribute substantial potential benefit to the utility function.

50 X SC ADT DL 2 1 1 4 8 0 000001 = + − − + −( ) + ∗ ∗    exp .     ( )2 where: X2 = the value function for scour risk mitigation; SC = the NBI scour rating code, Item 113, for a bridge; ADT = the average daily traffic, NBI rating Item 029; and DL = the detour length around the bridge, miles, rating Item 019. Generalized Value Functions for Bridges To generalize the scour example to the other utility attributes (i.e., the other categories of bridge needs), all of the value functions are expressed as a logit, or “S-shaped,” function given in general form in eq. 3 (Robert and Vlahos 2007, cited by Johnson 2008, p. 191). The specific relationships governing the value functions of all categories of bridge needs are shown in Table 10, together with explanations of parameters and the values of assigned weights. In developing these relationships and weights, Caltrans bridge engineers 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 NBI Scour Code Va lu e: D eg re e o f S co ur R is k M iti ga tio n FIGURE 2 Example value function for scour risk mitigation, X2. Attribute = Category of Bridge Need Key Para me ters Expression for C ( i ) in Eq. 3 Assigned Weight i = 1: Rehabilitation and replacem ent needs BHI Bridge Health Index BHI Change in BHI Due to Project TEV Total Element Value in Bridge ADT Average Daily Traffic DL Detour Length Around Bridge RU Repair Urgency 2.5 + 0.000001[(100 BHI BHI ) * TE V ]/100 + 0.00000001 * AD T * DL + 0.5 * (10 RU) 25% i = 2: Scour needs SC NBI Scour Code ADT Average Daily Traffic DL Detour Length Around Bridge 4 + (8 SC ) + 0.000001 * ADT * DL 20% i = 3: Bridge-rail upgrade needs RS Caltrans Bridge–Rail Upgrade Score 2 + RS 10% i = 4: Seismic retrofit needs Sv Caltrans Seismic Priority ADT Average Daily Traffic DL Detour Length Around Bridge 1.5 + Sv + 0.000001 * ADT * DL 25% i = 5: Mobility needs (raising/ strengthening) PIB Pontis Improvement Benefit 4.5 + 0.00015 * PIB 20% Source: Johnson (2008), Tables 1 and 2. Note: Author has changed some variable names slightly to increase comprehension. TABLe 10 CALTRANS VALUe-FUNCTION eLeMeNTS FOR FIVe CATeGORIeS OF BRIDGe NeeDS

51 sought to incorporate the set of key decision variables, draw on readily available bridge condition and rating information, and predict individual bridge-needs benefit values (Xi) and overall project utility (Ut) that would reflect the judgments of experienced bridge engineers. Trial use of the methodology and sensitivity analyses confirmed that individual value func- tions and total improvements in utility correlated highly with project priorities that would have been assigned by experi- enced bridge engineers. The utility approach that is based on eq. 1 has enabled Caltrans to analyze the programming of bridge projects across the diverse categories of bridge needs simultaneously, and to reflect the overall benefit of a project within a single utility value Ut (Johnson 2008, pp. 191–194). X C ii = + − ( )( ) 1 1 3exp ( ) where: Xi = the value function for attribute i, i = 1 to 5: that is, the value function for each category of bridge needs (refer to eq. 1); exp = the exponential function; C(i) = exponent for each attribute i, given in Table 10 (note that the negative of this value must be used in eq. 3). Values of these parameters are obtained from one of the following sources: NBI bridge ratings conducted by Caltrans according to the NBI Coding Guide (Recording and Coding Guide . . . Dec. 1995); departmental calculations of factors such as the BHI (Shepard and Johnson 2001), seismic retrofit priority Sv, and bridge rail upgrade score RS; the improvement- related benefit of projects, Pontis Improvement Benefit, as analyzed by the Pontis BMS used by Caltrans (technical refer- ence: Cambridge Systematics, Inc. 2005); and the Total ele- ment Value (TeV) of a bridge as defined in Caltrans’ bridge health index (BHI) formulas (Shepard and Johnson 2001), computed by Pontis as documented in its technical reference (Cambridge Systematics, Inc. 2005). An additional use of the TeV is explained in the following section. methods and measures Adjustment for Project Scale In applying the utility concept as a generalized measure of benefit for comparison to cost Caltrans realized one other adjustment was needed. The cost of a bridge project is influ- enced by many factors, but an important one is the scale or magnitude of the project, which is related to the size or value of the existing bridge. Given this dependence of cost on bridge scale, it was necessary to compensate on the ben- efit side to provide a fair assessment of benefit (or utility) to cost, bearing in mind that the utility is a dimensionless, zero-to-one number that does not retain any information on project scale. (This discussion applies to risk mitigation, but not necessarily to bridge rehabilitation work. Although risk mitigation is blind to bridge size, bridge rehabilitation considerations by Caltrans make use of a BHI, which does account for the relative size of the structure.) Among sev- eral possibilities for accounting for bridge scale, Caltrans selected the TeV parameter described in Table 10. The final measure of “benefit–cost,” or measure of cost-effectiveness structured such as a benefit–cost ratio, is given in eq. 4. Project Utility B C ratio Project_Cost= ∗U TEVt ( )4 where all benefits variables are as defined earlier, and Project_ Cost is the cost of the proposed project developed by Caltrans’ Office of Specialty Investigations & Bridge Management as part of its SHOPP program building. Illustration of Utility as a Benefit Measure for Bridges A simple arithmetic example illustrates how the Ut benefit measure operates to distinguish relative benefits of proj- ects on different bridges, a key step in project programming (Johnson 2008, p. 193). The example includes both a condi- tion-related need (rehabilitation and replacement) and a risk- related need (mitigation of scour-related risk); a combination that Caltrans believes demonstrates the power of the util- ity concept. Consider two bridges with similar structures but with different combinations of condition and scour needs, as shown in Table 11. Assume two projects for bridges A and B, respectively that address both condition and scour needs. • Bridge A has ratings that indicate a condition-related value (X1) of 0.20. Its NBI scour rating is 8, which denotes no scour (X2 = 0; refer to Figure 2). The con- tribution of these values to the project utility computed for Bridge A is shown in the last column of Table 11 to be 0.05, using the weights for condition and scour in Table 10. Structure Condition Value, X 1 NBI Rating of Scour Risk (Item 113) Scour Value, X 2 Contribution to Utility U t (weighted sum of X 1 and X 2 ) Bridge A 0.20 8: no scour 0.0 0.25 * 0.20 + 0.20 * 0.0 = 0.05 Bridge B 0.20 3: scour is critical 0.75 0.25 * 0.20 + 0.20 * 0.75 = 0.20 TABLe 11 exAMPLe OF THe UTILITY CONCePT APPLIeD TO TWO BRIDGeS

52 • Bridge B also has ratings that indicate a condition value X1 = 0.20. Its NBI scour rating however is 3 (critical), which corresponds to a scour value X2 of 0.75 (Fig- ure 2). The contribution of these values to the utility of the project for Bridge B is 0.20, or four times the benefit value for Bridge A. The Caltrans Bridge Management Office has applied the set of value functions and weights to every state-owned bridge in the BMS, together with estimated project costs. Those bridges with the highest utility–cost ratios (eq. 4) were evaluated for possible inclusion in the SHOPP program. This exercise showed that the approach can be used successfully for an inventory of bridges of different size, material, and composition. Possible Future Modifications Caltrans noted a simplifying assumption in this initial develop- ment of a utility approach. It was assumed that the post-project condition and risk value functions would all be restored to an undamaged (“like new”) or no-risk state. This assumption was justified partly by a tenet of the SHOPP program: all needs should be addressed when a SHOPP project is undertaken. A possible future refinement is to reflect the relative effectiveness of different bridge treatments, in which the post-project value functions do not automatically assume complete correction of damage or complete removal of risk. (Although not discussed in the Caltrans paper, this refinement could also be a first step to representing a time dimension more explicitly within the total utility result.) Decision support A multi-step process is used to evaluate candidate bridge projects for SHOPP and to build a prioritized program, a process comprising the following steps: • A bridge inspection or an analysis of the bridge identi- fies bridge needs. • For bridge replacement needs or for needs that exceed a certain cost threshold, a peer review is required by internal Caltrans policy. The peer review, conducted by Structure Maintenance & Investigations personnel, documents the following: current issues with the bridge structure and materials performance, alternatives con- sidered for solving the problems, LCCAs that have been performed to compare these alternatives, and notes of remaining concerns. • The result of the peer review is a recommended strategy to deal with the identified problems on the bridge, orga- nized within a project. • A utility function is developed for each competing bridge need or proposed project, formulated as described in the previous section. A utility–cost ratio is computed (eq. 4). • The utility–cost ratios are used to create an initial order- ing of bridge priorities for purposes of planning. • More complete project data are developed in project study reports. These data are evaluated to further assess the project’s priority and its likelihood of being deliv- ered on schedule. • Depending on the result of this assessment, funds may be allocated to the project. Alternately, the project may be developed further without additional funding alloca- tion, until its likelihood of timely delivery improves. This issue of project delivery is a significant one for Cal- trans regarding bridge projects generally, and especially those projects in coastal zones or sensitive environmental areas, and those projects involving historic bridges. Internal Caltrans reviews have shown that (1) bridge projects are much more likely to require substantial environmental study than are highway projects generally; (2) the time needed to complete an environmental review for bridge projects averages 4 years for a Finding of No Significant Impact, and 8 years for an environmental Impact Study—both of which exceed the 4-year time frame of a given SHOPP pro- gram document; (3) the time needed to complete an envi- ronmental review for bridge projects is longest for bridges requiring Coastal Zone Conservation clearances, regardless of the type of environmental document required; for exam- ple, the average time to complete an environment Impact Study in this case is almost 11 years; and (4) the type of bridge work and its setting (e.g., whether over water) also affect the environmental clearance time—bridge widen- ing and bridge replacement projects are typically the most problematic. resources required and other Information Resources • Application of the utility-based approach to program- ming is performed by Caltrans staff. • Consultants assisted in developing the initial concepts and models. • The analytic tools needed are relatively simple; value- function calculations and their contributions to total utility can be handled in spreadsheet workbooks. • Data of the required currency, accuracy, and timeliness are generated through the federally mandated biennial bridge inspection program, the peer reviews that are conducted for certain bridge projects, and routine activi- ties performed as part of the programming process, such as preparation of cost estimates. • Caltrans has been a leader in promoting eeA within a wide range of departmental activities and analyses. Members of the department’s bridge unit served on the state-user advisory panel that assisted in the original development of the Pontis BMS. The agency has also developed detailed BCA products, the Cal-B/C series, for use at a project, corridor, or network level. Cal-B/C is applied in a later case example on Value Analysis (Caltrans’ implementation of Ve).

53 • Caltrans has an extensive organizational commitment and website resources dedicated to a wide range of top- ics in eeA. Among these topics are LCCA and BCA, supported by drill-down details on individual website pages to address each step of an analytic procedure and to explain the application of the correct method to par- ticular cases or situations. There is strong integration of economic concepts and methods within a number of Caltrans business processes, buttressed by comprehen- sive and detailed documentation. eConomICs-baseD traDeoff analysIs Introduction In its consideration of asset management systems for trans- portation infrastructure, the New York State DOT (NYSDOT) has sought to articulate the distinctive aspects of an “asset management approach” as compared with that of traditional infrastructure management systems. Several precepts that distinguish asset management have been identified to guide system design and development. A core capability in this approach is the conduct of tradeoff analyses among four major departmental programs or “goal areas”: pavements, bridges, safety, and mobility. To address a well-known stumbling block in analyzing such tradeoffs—the need for a common measure of benefit across different programs or projects—NYSDOT has looked to an economics-based measure, excess road user costs. Based on this concept, a prototype tradeoff analysis has been developed. Although this experimental procedure has not yet been implemented on an operational basis, it has been included in these case examples to illustrate a unique and inno- vative application of eeA. Within the framework established for this synthesis, this case example addresses programming or resource allocation at the highway corridor and network levels, affecting investments across multiple programs. role of economic analysis in Highway Investment This case example of a tradeoff analysis prototype is drawn from materials prepared by NYSDOT asset management staff: a paper published through TRB (Shufon and Adams 2003) and a slide presentation at the Fifth National Transportation Asset Management Workshop (Adams 2003). Summary informa- tion on this presentation in the context of other workshop dis- cussions is given in the workshop proceedings (Wittwer et al. 2004). Further background information on the NYSDOT trad- eoff analysis concept has been compiled by FHWA in its asset management case study series (“economics in Asset Manage- ment: The New York experience” 2003). Asset Management Framework In their consideration of the distinguishing features of asset management that could provide value-added information and insights, NYSDOT managers realized the following (Shufon and Adams 2003): • Traditional management approaches were organized vertically within each program or goal area (pavement management, bridge management, safety management, mobility or congestion management). These vertical per- spectives, often referred to as “stovepipes” or “silos,” enabled basic infrastructure data (e.g., inventory, cur- rent and historical condition, and performance) to be transformed into information useful to various business processes at different organizational levels: identification of investment needs, planning, programming, budget- ing, and so forth. • To provide additional benefits, an asset management system needed to go beyond these capabilities of exist- ing or legacy management systems; for example, an updated system architecture, advances in data collec- tion techniques, improved database design, or other advances that enabled better decisions based on bet- ter information. Lacking any beneficial contribution, “asset management systems” would simply represent the “buzzwords du jour.” • Although a vertical perspective on infrastructure man- agement processes was still needed, asset management also called for a horizontal consideration across programs or goal areas. This view would enable managers to con- sider multiple assets and the tradeoffs inherent in balanc- ing investment choices among them. A tradeoff analysis would integrate highway infrastructure decisions and provide a greater benefit to users. (Multimodal tradeoffs have also been addressed in the asset management litera- ture, but are not the focus of this synthesis.) These perspectives led NYSDOT managers to articulate the contributions of an asset management system within the following four precepts: [1] Asset management systems are decision support systems. They do not make decisions; people make decisions. The busi- ness foundation must be in place to support decision making. [2] It would be virtually impossible to cover all assets owned or administered by a transportation agency. Assets should be covered only by the umbrella asset management system in which trade-offs make sense. For example, it makes little sense to develop procedures for trade-off analysis between investment in pavement preventive maintenance and investment in specialized transit services for the handicapped. In addition, the individual or “silo” management system should be already operational for the asset to be covered by the umbrella system. Otherwise, costs for the inventory, condition assessment, and so forth, would be prohibitive. [3] Trade-off analysis can be conducted only if a common technical measure can be used to quantify benefits of diverse proj- ects: for example, a pavement project versus a mobility project. [4] Generally, these analysis methods involve an economic analysis of competing alternatives. Source: Shufon and Adams 2003, p. 38. Common Measures for Diverse Projects: Excess Road User Costs The third and fourth precepts underlay the application of eeA to tradeoff analyses. The commensurate measures selected by

54 NYSDOT managers were the excess road user costs associ- ated, respectively, with each of the department’s goal areas (or programs). These excess costs were defined as “incremental costs incurred by [highway] users . . . attributed to less than ideal operating conditions” (Shufon and Adams 2003, p. 40). excess user costs comprised three components: the cost of delays to travelers and freight, accident or crash costs, and VOC. examples of excess road user costs resulting from less than ideal conditions are the cost of additional tire wear because of rough pavement, the additional trip length (affect- ing both travel-time cost and vehicle operating expenses) imposed on truck travel owing to a posted bridge, and the cost of an accident that might have been prevented with an improved highway feature. Another way to view these costs is to regard them as “avoidable” costs, which provides the basis for treating them as the benefits of pavement, bridge, or safety-related road improvement projects. The treatment of excess user costs in each goal area is as follows (Shufon and Adams 2003, p. 40). Pavement-Related Excess User Costs Pavement-related road user costs are related by NYSDOT to the International Roughness Index (IRI). A threshold value of acceptable IRI can be established; the additional road user costs incident to higher IRI values would constitute excess user costs. The department had engaged Cornell University researchers to advise on specific analytic relationships; their recommen- dation was to adapt pavement management models that had been developed by Saskatchewan. NYSDOT’s application of these models quantified the pavement roughness effects on various components of road user costs: fuel, tire, and vehicle parts consumption; labor cost for vehicle repair; delays and diversion of traffic; and damage to cargo. Of these, NYSDOT found that the roughness-related excess user costs for fuel consumption, cargo damage, and delays or diversion were negligible and safely ignored in network analyses of the state-maintained highways. It was recognized that these results might not hold for local roads or other nonstate networks, where IRI values might be higher than on state highways. Bridge-Related Excess User Costs excess user costs related to bridges include detour costs (entailing travel time and vehicle operation) borne by truck traffic resulting from inadequate bridge and approach clearances and load postings, and acci- dent costs resulting from deficient bridge and approach geo- metry. NYSDOT staff identified sources of information on these relationships; for example, PONTIS (a software app- lication developed to assist in managing highway bridges and other structures) and research by Florida DOT (FDOT). The department adapted the FDOT models for its bridge-related excess user cost calculation. Safety-Related Excess User Costs excess user costs result- ing from accidents are derived from concentrations of crash locations, to which roadway characteristics can be a contri- buting cause. NYSDOT’s system for tracking accidents can identify High Accident Locations (HALs), which com- prise Priority Investigation Locations and Safety-Deficient Locations. • Priority Investigation Locations are highway locations at which the accident rate is more than three standard deviations higher than the mean rate for the comparable class of highway. • Safety-Deficient Locations are highway locations at which the accident rate is one to three standard deviations higher than the comparable mean rate. The excess user cost associated with HALs is computed as the product of the difference between the accident rate at each high-accident location and the comparable mean rate, and the average cost per accident obtained from NYSDOT accident data tables. Mobility-Related Excess User Costs excess user costs related to mobility—that is, congestion costs—arise from both recurring congestion problems and from individual high- way incidents. New York State defines congestion as “delay to persons and goods beyond a limit that can be tolerated”— quantitatively, the boundary between Levels of Service D and e. NYSDOT’s Congestion Needs Assessment Model can identify congested locations and calculate excess user costs as a function of vehicle hours of delay for both auto passengers and freight. However, NYSDOT has for the time being focused the tradeoff exercise on only the freight portion of these costs. (Computation of passenger values of time is beset by several analytic issues and motorist behavioral assumptions. Delays to freight are currently believed to be more clearly defined and supported analytically, and are more consistent with NYSDOT’s current priorities and decision- making practices.) methods and measures Highway System Levels for Computing Excess User Costs For each goal area of pavement, bridge, safety, and mobility, NYSDOT computes and assembles the measures of excess road user cost at three highway-system levels: 1. Individual asset: pavement segment, bridge structure, safety-deficient location, and mobility location. 2. Analysis link: length of highway between major inter- sections, comprising some portion of the individual assets discussed earlier. 3. Corridor: a highway route within a county, comprising some portion of the analysis links discussed earlier. New York State’s highway system consists of a total of 15,000 centerline-miles or 40,000 lane-miles. This system contains approximately 7,000 analysis links and 1,500 corridors.

55 Tradeoff Measures Measures used in the tradeoff analysis are structured as a benefit–cost ratio. • Benefits are defined as reductions in excess road user costs that are attributable to a corrective project. They are excess user costs that are now avoided. These ben- efits are computed as an annual figure. • Costs are agency expenditures for the project. To con- vert costs to an annual basis, the project expenditures are multiplied by a capital recovery factor as a function of the service life of the project and the current depart- mental discount rate. • The benefit–cost ratio is computed using the annual benefit divided by the annualized cost. This computa- tion is performed at the asset, link, and corridor levels described in the previous section. prototyping Decision support Because the NYSDOT research was confined to a prototyp- ing stage, examples of actual decision support are not avail- able. However, departmental staff developed reports that illustrate the type of information that could be made avail- able to decision makers needing a better understanding of investment tradeoffs. Two example reports for a hypothetical highway corridor are shown in Tables 12 and 13: • Table 12 displays information on excess user costs esti- mated for each goal area by link in the corridor. In addi- tion to total excess user costs among all goal areas, it includes an estimate of “base” user costs; that is, costs that are not considered “excess.” The ratio of excess to base user costs in the rightmost column is an indication of the excess-user-cost “tax” borne by each motorist because of deficiencies in key highway assets in this corridor. • Table 13 displays the corridor benefit–cost information that would be computed as described in the previous sec- tion. The benefit–cost ratios are viewed by NYSDOT as indicators suggesting potential candidates for program investments, warranting further investigation and analy- sis. It is also the view of NYSDOT staff that “the power of the [benefit–cost] approach is the capability to assess the investment potential for groups of diverse assets taken together, such as links and corridors” (Shufon and Adams 2003, p. 44). Tables 12 and 13 can be analyzed vertically or horizon- tally. Vertical comparisons consider potential investments within a program; horizontal comparisons, among programs. NYSDOT personnel also envisioned that results shown in these two tables could be displayed not only by the aggre- gations of assets shown (individual asset, link, and cor- ridor), but also by other delineations; for example, route, county, functional classification, traffic-volume groupings, or other available parameters. economic and demographic data would also accompany these analyses, allowing sum- maries to be prepared, for example, for areas suffering low economic growth, where reduction of excess transportation user costs could be targeted to improve the local economy. resources required and other Information Implementation Issues and Challenges Given its status as a prototyping exercise, this case example has not yet developed a track record of resources to be applied in conducting actual tradeoff analyses. Suffice it to say that the proposed analysis, intended as part of NYSDOT’s asset management system for its transportation infrastructure, is Analy sis Link EU C Pavement EU C Bridge EU C Safety EU C Mobility Total EUC for Link Est. Base User Cost Excess/Base User Cost L1 50 — 100 — 150 7,000 2.1% L2 40 40 — — 80 6,000 1.3% L3 — 30 — 20 50 3,000 1.7% L4 — 80 40 30 150 10,000 1.5% L5 120 100 50 100 370 10,000 3.7% L6 90 — 60 110 260 10,000 2.6% Corridor Totals 300 250 250 260 1,060 46,000 2.3% Source: Shufon and Adams (2003), Figure 6, p. 42. Notes: EUC = Excess [Highway] User Costs. — = no excess user costs assumed to occur. TABLe 12 exAMPLe exCeSS-USeR-COST OUTPUT FOR A CORRIDOR ($000S)

Pavement Bridge Safety Mobility Link Totals Analysis Link Annual EUC Avoided Annual- ized Project Cost Bene- fit– Cost Ratio Annual EUC Avoided Annual- ized Project Cost Bene- fit– Cost Ratio Annual EUC Avoided Annual- ized Project Cost Bene- fit– Cost Ratio Annual EUC Avoided Annual- ized Project Cost Bene- fit– Cost Ratio Annual EUC Avoided Annual- ized Project Cost Bene- fit– Cost Ratio L1 50 40 1.2 — — — 100 50 2.0 — — — 150 90 1.7 L2 40 60 0.7 40 20 2.0 — — — — — — 80 80 1.0 L3 — — — 30 50 0.6 — — — 20 100 0.2 50 150 0.3 L4 — — — 80 60 1.3 40 40 1.0 30 20 1.5 150 120 1.3 L5 120 200 0.6 100 80 1.3 50 50 1.0 100 200 0.5 370 530 0.7 L6 90 50 1.8 — — — 60 110 0.5 110 100 1.1 260 260 1.0 Corridor Totals 300 350 0.8 250 210 1.2 250 250 1.0 260 420 0.6 1,060 1,230 0.9 Source: Shufon and Adams (2003), Figure 7, p. 43. Notes: EUC = Excess [Highway] User Costs. — = no excess user costs assumed to occur. TABLe 13 SAMPLe BeNeFIT–COST OUTPUT FOR A CORRIDOR (COSTS ANNUALLY IN $000S)

57 supported by a number of individual management systems and data collection, processing, and analysis activities. The analysis has been conceived by NYSDOT asset manage- ment personnel, with the support of university and industry research in the development of component models of asset performance. The NYSDOT researchers did, however, identify issues that they perceived would be challenges in bringing the tradeoff analysis to actual practice (Shufon and Adams 2003, p. 44): • The first issue is the availability of realistic agency costs to reduce or eliminate excess road user costs. Pavement and bridge costs are available from pavement manage- ment and bridge management systems, respectively. These systems include decision-support algorithms that seek to identify the preferred treatment to address defi- cient conditions and performance. However, the same is not true for safety and mobility. There is a range of safety and mobility actions to address highway sections exhibiting similar performance (e.g., numbers of HALs or vehicle hours of delay). Specifying preferred treat- ments within an investment tradeoff analysis, prior to detailed studies of specific site conditions and factors, is complicated. NYSDOT is studying the issue to see if average costs of safety and mobility actions can be estimated for use in the denominator of the B/C calculation. • The second issue concerns the use of avoided excess highway-user costs as the measure of benefits to com- pare the worth of projects across diverse programs. “Base costs” and “excess costs” imply a threshold value dividing the two categories; this threshold must be chosen with care. For example, too low a value for a particular program would encourage overinvestment in that program. To counter this tendency, the NYSDOT researchers recommended that the asset management sys- tem recommendations, including the tradeoff results, be reviewed by, and calibrated to, “the professional experience of a panel of experts who are responsible for regional program development.” These results would then be “presented to NYSDOT executive management for policy guidance.” • The third issue deals with the scope of the proposed analysis, which is at a highway system or network level, and is based on relative performance (avoided excess user costs) rather than asset condition specifically (e.g., pavement, bridge, safety, or operations needs or deficiencies). The implication is that there is still an important need for management systems that address individual assets; for example, pavement management and bridge management systems. The tradeoff analy- sis relies on these systems for recommended treatment actions and costs, as discussed earlier. Furthermore, these individual asset systems analyze options that are not considered in the tradeoff approach proposed earlier. – For example, the tradeoff analysis does not consider preventive maintenance policies that could lengthen life expectancy of pavements now in smooth con- dition (and which therefore have not yet triggered excess user costs). – Nor does the tradeoff analysis consider the penal- ties of deferred maintenance in terms of the addi- tional future agency cost that will be incurred, for example, by delaying correction of bridge structural deficiencies. Notwithstanding these limitations, the tradeoff analysis is viewed realistically as an additional decision-support tool that provides comparative information horizontally across highway investment programs as well as vertically within them. As a component of an asset management system, it complements, but does not replace, information available from current systems that manage individual assets. pavement type seleCtIon Introduction The use of LCCA for pavement type selection appears to be one of the more widespread uses of engineering economic methods in the United States, as shown by surveys (including the results obtained for this synthesis) that are presented in chapter two. A case example of this application of economic methods thus helps to identify the characteristics of LCCA use across the United State. Results from recent surveys at a broad level will be used to illustrate nationwide patterns as well as the diversity in selection of key parameters such as discount rate. Discussions will then focus on two particular state DOTs to identify specific policies, methods, and other characteristics of LCCA use. Within the framework of this synthesis, these LCCA applications relate to project-level design and development. role of economic analysis in Highway Investment Pavement-Oriented Federal Guidance The FHWA has issued several guidance documents on the use of LCCA in pavement design and type selection, invest- ment analyses of investments at other stages of the pavement life cycle, and for related purposes such as alternate bidding. For purposes of this case example, the relevant guidance is included in the FHWA’s Final Policy Statement (“LCCA Final Policy Statement” Aug. 29, 1996). Information on the engineering aspects of pavement design and performance and how they can be incorporated within life-cycle analyses is given in the FHWA’s Technical Bulletin on the subject (Life Cycle Cost Analysis . . . Sep. 1998). Through its Final Policy Statement, FHWA supports and encourages the use of LCCA to analyze investment alternatives for pavement design, and outlines principles of good practice that might

58 be followed regardless of the methodology used. Among these principles are the following (“LCCA Final Policy Statement” Aug. 29, 1996): • Life-cycle costs should be considered in all phases of a pavement’s life cycle: construction, maintenance, reha- bilitation, and operation. • Analysis periods should be long enough to capture long-term differences in discounted costs among com- peting alternatives and rehabilitation strategies. These periods should encompass several maintenance and rehabilitation cycles, and for some pavement designs may include reconstruction as well. • All significant differences in agency and user costs bet- ween alternatives should be considered in the analysis. • Considerable uncertainties in key aspects of the analy- sis should be recognized and addressed through quan- titative and qualitative assessments such as sensitivity analysis, probabilistic techniques or risk analysis, expert panels, or other mechanisms. • Streams of agency and user costs through the analysis period should be discounted to net present value (or converted to equivalent uniform annual cost) using dis- count rates that are consistent with OMB Circular A-94. In a subsequent clarification of FHWA policy regarding alternate pavement type bidding, FHWA noted that “discount rates should be consistent with OMB Circular A-94” and that “The trend over the past 10 years indicates a [real] discount rate in the range of 2 to 4 percent is reasonable.” The FHWA guidance also requires that any price adjustments used in comparing alternate pavement types during bid evaluation must be approved under Special experimental Project #14, commonly referred to as SeP-14 (Stephanos Nov. 13, 2008). The FHWA has produced a software package, RealCost, as a spreadsheet workbook that conducts LCCAs of pave- ment alternatives at the project level (RealCost User Manual May 2004). A number of state DOTs employ RealCost in analyzing pavement type-selection options. State DOT Guidance As state DOT examples, California and Colorado have issued guidance documents addressing LCCA use for pave- ment investment analyses. • Caltrans has issued a policy statement directing the use of LCCA for most projects involving pavement work on the state highway system, regardless of funding source (exceptions are noted in the policy document). Corresponding changes have been made to the agency’s design manual and project development manual (Land Mar. 7, 2007). Procedures for conducting pavement project analyses within Caltrans, using FHWA’s Real- Cost software, are outlined in a Caltrans procedures manual (Life-Cycle Cost Analysis Procedures Manual Nov. 2007). Concurrently with this synthesis proj- ect, Caltrans is involved in NCHRP Synthesis 42-08 to investigate full-scale accelerated pavement testing (APT). The APT-related synthesis includes consider- ation of the economic costs and benefits of full-scale APT research, using the methods and criteria described in chapter two of this report (Steyn 2012). • The Colorado DOT (CDOT) issues its guidance in the form of procedural reports. CDOT’s history of written procedures for LCCA goes back to 1972. Although the original process remains essentially in place, it has been updated several times in the intervening years, with the latest update coming in 2009 (Harris 2009). CDOT also uses RealCost to conduct a probabilistic LCCA, primarily to compare alternatives in asphalt and con- crete pavements. methods and measures In 2005–2006 a two-staged survey was conducted by Clem- son University for the South Carolina DOT (SCDOT) on the use of LCCA for pavement type selection (Rangaraju et al. 2008). These findings are noteworthy because they provide an indication of agency practices in LCCA nationwide. Sev- eral of the findings below report data from the Stage 1 sur- vey, which elicited 35 responses. Among the findings of this survey were the following, focusing on the economic dimen- sion of the responses: • Thirty-two of 35 agencies, or 91%, reported that they use LCCA as part of the decision process for selecting pavement type. • Fifteen agencies (47%) reported using specialized soft- ware for LCCA; for example, RealCost and Darwin (an AASHTOWare product). • Thirteen agencies (41%) include user costs in their analyses; 19 (59%) reported that they do not. • The responses indicated a distribution of lengths of analysis period used in LCCA. Among 27 respondents, 4% used 20 to 29 years; 30% used 30 to 39 years; 40% used 40 to 49 years; and 26% used 50 to 59 years. • There were also considerable ranges of values in the initial performance lives of flexible and rigid pave- ments. Flexible pavements elicited responses extending from 10 to 14 years to 30 to 34 years. Rigid pavement responses extended from 15 to 19 years to 35 to 40 years. Recommended values by CDOT and Caltrans fall within the ranges of values cited earlier for each parameter, but exhibit the individual differences in practice between the agencies. For example, regarding lengths of the recommended analysis period, CDOT now recommends 40 years, whereas Caltrans recommends a range of values from 20 years to 55 years that depends on the respective alternatives being compared. The rationale of the two agencies in their selection of discount rate

59 is also interesting to compare. Although both agencies arrive at a rate that conforms to FHWA guidance, they arrive at their recommendation in different ways. • Caltrans considered the national data supporting a dis- count rate that was reported in OMB Circular A-94, and decided to compare those data with local experi- ence. It considered returns to the state’s Pooled Money Investment Account, a repository for surplus state cash, and found real returns for the past 20 and 30 years of 2.8% and 3.2%, respectively. Although the California data were backward-looking and the OMB data (OMB Circular A-94, Appendix C) are forward-looking, both suggested a real discount rate of 3%. The Caltrans team, which was considering changing the discount rate in its Cal-B/C benefit–cost program, was uncomfortable with a significant reduction from 5% (the former dis- count rate in Cal-B/C) to the proposed 3%, and opted instead for the compromise value of 4%. This rate is the Caltrans default value for all its BCAs. The Cal- trans team recommended that future changes to the Cal- B/C discount rate be based on the OMB Circular A-94 Appendix C data directly, which are readily available and updated annually (System Metrics Group, Inc. et al. Feb. 2009, pp. III-2–III-5). • CDOT recently updated its approach to setting a dis- count rate. The approach is based on the 10-year mov- ing average of the 30-year Real Treasury interest rates reported in OMB Circular A-94, Appendix C. This computation reflects, in CDOT’s view, a stable estimate of interest rates corresponding to the most conserva- tive, longest maturity investment strategy—a criterion appropriate to the assumption of a 40-year analysis period. When CDOT uses the 10-year moving aver- age, the analysis covers a span of 20 years of averages, smoothing out the fluctuations. even so, each year has a slight change in the computed interest rate. Because CDOT’s intent is to use a stable, no changing yearly rate, an additional check is performed: to compare the current CDOT discount rate with the 10-year moving average plus or minus two standard deviations. Only if the interest rate changes more than two standard deviations from the current CDOT rate will a new dis- count rate be determined. This comparison is checked annually. For 2008 data, CDOT computed the 10-year moving average for 1999–2008 as 3.3%, which is the recommended discount rate (Harris 2009, pp. 5–8). For 2010, the discount rate remained at 3.3%. Decision support FHWA and the state DOTs recognize that precise cost esti- mates and precise knowledge of life-cycle actions (e.g., the performance of pavement maintenance and repair) are not possible for the long analysis periods that are recommended. Many agencies therefore introduce a tolerance when compar- ing LCCA results, recognizing that small differences in cost may be the result of inherent uncertainties, and not to material differences between pavement alternatives. The Clemson– SCDOT nationwide survey indicated that, of 32 res ponses, 4 states base their pavement decision on the alternative with the lowest present value; eight selected the lowest-cost alternative if the cost difference exceeded 10%; and one res- pondent used a threshold value of 5%, another 15%, and yet another 20%. If the cost differences between alternatives are less than these threshold values, then one or a group of decision makers (e.g., a regional pavement designer or a pavement selection panel) makes the final decision. Other factors besides lowest life-cycle cost that are considered include constructability, material availability, design and envi- ronmental factors, continuity of pavement type, traffic control costs, availability of qualified constructors, and public/political issues (Rangaraju et al. 2008, p. 36). • Caltrans uses a tolerance threshold of 5% between alternatives, or 2% if initial costs exceed $100 million (Life-Cycle Cost Analysis Procedures Manual Nov. 2007, p. 80). • With its probabilistic approach, CDOT bases its deci- sion on a comparison of the probabilistic results of the two alternatives when evaluated at a 75% confidence level (Harris 2009, p. 4). • The use of probabilistic results in this way was also dis- cussed by Rangaraju et al. as an effective way of manag- ing risk. A threshold value of less than 100% recognizes that while using a 100% confidence level removes all risk from the evaluation, the result may not be economical. In addition to CDOT’s threshold criterion, Maryland’s 85% confidence limit was also cited (Rangaraju et al. 2008, p. 57). resources required and other Information Resources The resources required are implied by the previous discus- sion: knowledge of applicable guidelines, development of required data, and knowledge of the LCCA tools that are used. Responses to the Clemson–SCDOT survey indicated that, of 22 agencies that use LCCA for pavement type selec- tion and that responded to the second-stage survey, 15 agen- cies (68%) were satisfied or had only minor concerns with their respective processes; 7 agencies (32%) had significant concerns about current LCCA application to pavement type selection. Among these issues were the following (Rangaraju et al. 2008, pp. 38–39, 81): • Unreliable data quality. • Lack of adequate training regarding LCCA programs such as RealCost, and inadequate understanding of the significance and implications of the input parameters to these programs.

60 • Difficulty in predicting materials costs given their rapid and significant fluctuations in price. • Lack of sufficient historical performance data for newer pavement designs and materials (from which to esti- mate service life and rehabilitation/maintenance needs reliably and credibly for LCCA). • Lack of “rational and predictable triggers” that signal the need for rehabilitation and maintenance. • Lack of agreement with the asphalt and pavement con- struction industries on key parameters that are input to the LCCA. • Concerns “from a political/market standpoint; that is, LCCA is not popular.” Issues raised by Canadian agencies in the same study reflected some similar concerns; for example, regarding data and methods, and need for training. Canadian respondents also cited lack of communication within agencies and between agency and political officials. value engIneerIng Introduction The latest (2008) FHWA statistics on the use of Ve by state DOTs show that among 382 studies completed nationwide, 139 (36%) were accounted for by 4 states (“FY 2008 Value . . .” 2009). Of these, the top two states, Florida and Califor- nia, accounted for 82 studies, or 21%. This section presents two case examples, California and Florida, on a comparative basis to highlight similarities and differences. Florida refers to its effort as Ve; California’s process is discussed as Value Analysis, or VA. The two terms are treated synonymously in this section. When discussing the topic generally or when refer- ring to Florida, Ve will be used; when referring to California’s approach specifically, Value Analysis or VA will be used. Ve is a systematic, structured process that reviews and ana- lyzes a project typically during the concept development and design phases (“Value engineering” 2010). Although Ve may also apply during the construction phase, inviting suggestions by the contractor for an improved product, this case focuses on the project level and the design phase of the development cycle. The following discussion is limited to conventional con- struction projects and does not address design–build. Further information on Ve practices among highway transporta- tion agencies in the United States and Canada is provided in NCHRP Synthesis 352, including FHWA and OMB regula- tory requirements for using Ve (Wilson 2005). role of economic analysis in Highway Investment FDOT defines Ve in its guidance as follows: Value engineering is the systematic application of recognized techniques by a multi-disciplined team which identifies the func- tion of a product or service; establishes a worth for that function; generates alternatives through the use of creative thinking; and provides the needed functions to accomplish the original intent of the project, reliably and at the lowest life-cycle cost without sacrificing project requirements for safety, quality, operations, maintenance, and environment. Source: Value Engineering Pro- gram, May 15, 2008, p. 2. The FHWA noted that the multi-disciplinary team appointed to conduct a Ve analysis consists of persons who are not involved in the project and must include “at least one individual who is trained and knowledgeable in Ve tech- niques and able to serve as the team’s facilitator and coordi- nator” (“Order . . .” May 25, 2010). Project recommendations potentially provide the following benefits (“Value engineer- ing” 2010): • Providing needed functions safely, reliably, efficiently, and at lowest overall cost; • Improving the value and quality of the project; and • Reducing the time to complete the project. Caltrans identifies additional, more specific benefits in its guidance Project Development Procedures Manual (PDPM Chapter 19, p. 19–7; Value Analysis Team Guide 2003, p. 1.3): • To foster a team approach to problem-solving and proj- ect development; • To help build consensus among stakeholders; • To identify and develop strategies that avoid or mitigate risks and associated costs; and • To identify opportunities for Context Sensitive Solutions. Ve is an outgrowth of work in private industry during World War II focusing on managing value and innovation in a systematic way. The driving force was the wartime scarcity of critical materials, with impacts on U.S. defense manufacturers. The crucial insight was: If these materials were understood in terms of the functions they performed, then a focus on the function—function analysis—could, with creative thinking, lead to alternate materials, or dif- ferent design concepts or manufacturing approaches, that might achieve the same function. This logic was later for- malized in a “value analysis” process (Value Standard . . . June 2007). Ve in the public sector builds on these concepts of the analysis of value and function. The process has a long history of use by federal agencies, including its requirement in trans- portation beginning four decades ago. The FHWA maintains an active website on Ve policy, practice, and accomplish- ment (www.fhwa.dot.gov/ve/). AASHTO provides guidance on Ve (Guidelines for Value Engineering 2010), and state DOTs typically issue further guidance on Ve within their own programs. Table 14 identifies the scope of Ve as required by FHWA for federal-aid highways, and by the two case example states

61 for nonfederal-aid projects. Table 15 describes team compo- sition, process overview, and presentation of results as speci- fied by California and Florida. At the heart of the economic evaluation is a BCA. The scale of the Ve analysis that will be needed depends on the scale of the project itself and other elements such as need for environmental review. Major projects will require a longer period for Ve analysis, and more than one analysis may be called for at different stages through concept devel- opment, environmental review, and design. methods and measures The life-cycle costs and benefits supporting the Ve proposals are applications of the net-present-value method applied to a TABLe 14 SCOPe OF VALUe eNGINeeRING PROGRAM Scope or Scheduling Item California DOT Value Analysis Florida DOT Value Engineering Federal-Aid Highway Projects; Federal-Aid Bridge Projects (i.e., those that use FAHP funding, whether or not on Federal-Aid sy stem ) All projects $25 million Bridge projects $20 million Costs above encom pass desi gn, ROW, construction, project support U.S.DOT secretary ma y require VE (e.g., projects $500 million, or projects “of special interest”) No waivers or exceptions All projects $25 million Bridge projects $20 million Costs above encom pass desi gn, ROW, construction, project support U.S.DOT secretary may require VE (e.g., projects $500 million, or projects “of special interest”) No waivers or exceptions Non-Federal-Aid Projects All projects $25 million Bridge projects $20 million Costs above encom pass desi gn, ROW, construction, project support U.S.DOT secretary ma y require VE (e.g., projects $500 million, or projects “of special interest”) No waivers or exceptions Projects $25 million Waiver may be requested case-by- case; director of Transportation Development must approve in writing for single project District flexibility to conduct VE on projects below $25 m illion threshold Typical Candidates Am ong Projects Less Than $25 Million Threshold VA “should be” perform ed on projects $15 million to enhance project value through use of VA and to avoid need to apply VA later in project developm ent [PDPM, p. 19-7]. Caltrans districts are encouraged to vol untarily identify studies. Criteria might include; e.g., projects with: potential cost overruns, few iden tified alternatives, high maintenance costs, difficult safety/construction/ operational/ROW/ maintenance/ environm ental issues, com plex geom etry, ma jo r structures. Specific examples of candidate projects are not cited, but guidance docum ents support a broad scope of potential VA applications, in cluding highway construction projects, highway product studies, and Caltrans process studies. VA can be used to build consensus am ong stakeholders Projects substantially exceeding initial cost estimate Complex projects; capacity projects Corridor studies; interchanges Projects requested for VE by PM Projects with high ROW costs Projects, processes with unusual proble ms Scheduling by Phase Any stage of project development and construction, although VA is most effective in early stages of developm ent process For DB: prior to RFP release. One of following: Planning, Project Developm ent & Environm ental (PD&E), Initial Engineering Design For DB: prior to RFP release. Sources: PDPM, Chapter 19; Value Analysis Team Guide 2003; Value Engineering Program 2008. Regarding Caltrans requirements for non-federal-aid projects: Caltrans policy states that federal VE requirements for highway projects of $25 million or more (bridge projects of $20 million or more) apply regardless of funding source (Deputy Directive DD-92 July 2007). Therefore, non-federal-aid projects have the same VE requirements as federal-aid projects (based on 2007 SAFETEA-LU requirements). Notes: = “equal to or greater than”; DB = design-build; FAHP = Federal-Aid Highway Program; PDPM = Project Development Procedures Manual; PM = project manager; RFP = Request for Proposals; ROW = right-of-way; VA = value analysis; VE = value engineering.

62 TABLe 15 VA/Ve TeAM, TOOLS, AND ReSULTS Item California DOT Value Analysis Florida DOT Value Engineering Typical VA/VE Team Composition VA team selection is initiated by the DVAC and co mp leted by the VA Tea m Leader in coordination with the DVAC, PM, and others attending a pre-study meeting. Key disciplines/functions needed on the project study should be represented. DVAC should contact function ma nagers in advance of the st udy to identify and recruit candidate members. Roster lists VA team leaders and full-tim e study team me mb ers, project contacts, team resource advisors, study technical reviewers, and project decision ma kers. Expertise levels are identified for all except external stakeholders and decision ma kers. VA team members should be at either advanced or expert levels. VE team selection coordinated between DVE and PM. Me mb ership structured to include appropriate expertise to evaluate ma jor aspects of project. Minim um : design, construction, and maintenance should be represented. Federal-Aid projects: personnel involved in design are inform ation resources, but should not be team me mb ers. Districts determine whether membership comprises FDOT personnel, consultants, or combination. Study Elements Preparation Initiate study Organize study Prepare data VA Study Segment 1 Inform team Analyze functions Create ideas Evaluate ideas Segment 2 Develop alternatives, including LCC, benefits, and costs Critique alternatives Present alternatives Segment 3 Assess alternatives Resolve alternatives Present results: summarize performance, value, and cost improvements Report Publish results Close out VA study 1. Define original project objective 2. Identify design criteria for project 3. Verify all valid project constraints 4. Identify specifically the components and elements of high cost 5. Determine basic and secondary functions 6. Evaluate the alternatives by comparison 7. Consider life-cycle costs of alternatives 8. Develop detailed implementation plan 9. Determine which VE alternatives can be grouped together and which stand alone. Select the combination of solutions to recommend specifically. Presentation of Results Description of alternative Sketches (original design and alternative) Calculations Benefits Initial costs LCC Description of alternatives Advantage/disadvantage comparison Evaluation matrix with weighted criteria Sketches: base design, proposed design Discussion, pros and cons Cost summary (see below) with supporting calculations Form of Economic Results Initial cost, annual cost, subsequent single costs (e.g., for repair, rehabilitation, and salvage value), and total LCC computed at specified discount rate Above costs computed for base design and alternative design. Yields result: Total Present Value Cost of each alternative, and difference between the two. Discount rate used in example reviewed: 4% Initial cost, annual cost, and total LCC computed at specified discount rate Above costs reported for base design, proposed design (including implementation costs), and difference between base design and proposed design options. Yields result: either cost savings or the additional cost due to adopting the proposed design. Discount rate used in example reviewed: 7% Sources: TVI International (1999); Value Analysis Team Guide (2003); Value Engineering Program (2008). Notes: DVAC = District Value Analysis Coordinator; DVE = District Value Engineer; LCC = life-cycle costs; PM = project manager; VA = value analysis; VE = value engineering.

63 specified period (e.g., 20 years) at the discount rate indicated in Table 15. examples of cost-benefit information used in and produced by a VA analysis are as follows (TVI Inter- national 1999). Project Cost Information in Value Analysis (Caltrans example) These cost items are computed by year for the base design and the proposed design alternative: • Direct project costs: right-of-way, construction, and project support. • Subsequent costs: maintenance and operations, rehab- ilitation. • Mitigation costs: environmental mitigation actions for air quality, water quality, noise control, etc. • Other costs: as specified by VA team. • Total costs: totaled in constant dollars by year through the analysis period, with computation of present value. Road User Cost Information in Value Analysis (Caltrans example) These data items are computed by year for the base design and the proposed design alternative: • Travel time: average annual traffic volume, total travel time, travel time reduction owing to the defined alter- native, and travel time savings in constant dollars by year through the analysis period, with computation of present value. • Vehicle operating cost (VOC): annual vehicle-miles of travel, total VOC, and VOC savings in constant dollars by year through the analysis period, with computation of present value. • Accident cost: annual vehicle-miles of travel, annual number of accidents, accident cost savings as a result of the indicated reduction in number of accidents under the proposed design alternative; these cost savings are expressed in constant dollar by year through the analy- sis period, with computation of present value. Tally of Cost and Benefit Results for VA (Caltrans Example) • Net present value: computed by subtracting the pres- ent value of total project costs from the present value of total user savings comprising savings in travel-time costs, VOC, and accident costs. • Internal rate of return: computed by testing at what dis- count rate the total (constant-dollar) benefits and the total (constant-dollar) costs are equal. If the computed IRR is greater than the discount rate used to conduct the analysis (i.e., 4% in Table 15), then the IRR result is equivalent to benefits exceeding costs and the net pres- ent value being positive; that is, the project alternative is economically justified. As a further note on applications, Table 14 indicates that Caltrans’ scope of VA analyses can include products and processes, in addition to transportation projects. examples of these types of studies have been cited by FHWA in its Ve website: In addition to studies conducted for the Federal-Aid Highway Program, Caltrans utilizes the Ve techniques [Caltrans’ VA pro- cess] to recently analyze improvements proposed for their ‘Utili- ties Database’ and ‘Purpose and Need’ processes. Caltrans also used Ve to study a series of Safety Rest Area projects that had come in over estimated budgets to develop alternative ways to reduce construction cost while maintaining or improving project quality. Source: “FY 2007 Annual Federal-aid . . .” 2008. Decision support An example of subsequent review and implementation of VA findings is provided by a Caltrans example for a new State Route, SR-138 (“Value Analysis Study . . .” 2009): • VA team recommendations were submitted for review to identified agency managers and stakeholders; a 4-week review period was allotted. This particular study involved 11 VA alternatives. • Following review, an implementation meeting was held to resolve the disposition of the 11 alternatives. An updated set of alternatives to be developed was agreed to by the VA team members. • The VA team formally developed the agreed-on alterna- tives and suggestions that were accepted by the majority of stakeholders. (Note the entry in Table 14 that Caltrans guidance recognizes the use of VA to help build consen- sus among stakeholders.) • These updating findings of the VA team were applied in the developmental phase of the project. resources needed and other Information Resources Overall team composition in FDOT is a district decision. Consultants often produce the Ve reports, although there is no policy that dictates this practice. California’s VA team composition is likewise tailored for each project, including representatives from the DOT, local stakeholders, consultants, and academics; the team may also use consultants to pro- duce VA reports. Caltrans also explicitly considers the level of expertise for team members who are not stakeholders or agency decision makers. Key disciplines typically represented on a Ve/VA team might include the following, as appropriate to the specific project: highway design, bridges or other struc- tures, infrastructure construction, traffic operations (including access to modeling capability if user costs-benefits are to be

64 compresses the time schedule and begins to constrain the ability to make changes; and limitations on resources avail- able (e.g., limits on Caltrans participation in local VA studies or the inability to schedule good meeting rooms for the time needed) (Tusup and Hays 2009). aCCeleratIon of projeCt DelIvery Introduction The Minnesota DOT (Mn/DOT) applies economic analysis to a number of transportation issues that it faces and main- tains a website providing guidance on benefit–cost meth- ods (“Benefit–Cost Analysis for Transportation . . .” n.d.). Recently it applied economic concepts and methods to exam- ine the benefits and costs of accelerating project delivery (HDRHLB Decision economics Inc. 2006). On-time, on- budget project delivery is becoming a major issue among national, state, and local transportation organizations across the nation. Streamlining project approvals and permits, together with accelerated project design and construction, are seen as critical to cost saving, improving mobility and safety, and maintaining economic competitiveness, while successfully preserving environmental quality and energy efficiency. Accelerating project schedules also entails risks, however, as in potentially greater mobilization costs and the possibility of missing and having to correct project details. Mn/DOT therefore sought to develop a methodological approach to analyzing the economic impacts of accelerating project delivery, accounting for the risks involved, and pos- sible ways to mitigate these risks. In terms of the criteria for including this Mn/DOT work within this synthesis, the study is unique: It was believed to be a “first” in developing a “compre- hensive methodological approach to estimating the economic impacts of transportation project delivery acceleration,” and to assessing the risk–reward tradeoffs of accelerated-delivery mechanisms such as design–build (HDRHLB Decision economics Inc. 2006, p. v). The case study used by Mn/ DOT and its consultant to illustrate this approach was State Highway 52 in Rochester (ROC 52). In terms of the research framework established for this synthesis, this case example is at the individual highway project level, focusing on the project delivery stage. role of economic analysis in Highway Investment Risk-Reward Framework The rewards of accelerating highway project completion are described in the Mn/DOT study as follows (HDRHLB Decision economics Inc. 2006): • The highway agency saves costs by reducing the effects of general inflation on project expenses as well as the impacts of possibly more rapid cost increases in items that are unique to highway construction; for example, estimated), environmental protection and mitigation, and maintenance and operations. The tabulation of agency and road-user costs and benefits and the comparison of costs to benefits are accomplished using the Cal-B/C program (System Metrics Group, Inc. and Cambridge Systematics, Inc. 2004). Part of the information anticipated to be needed by the VA team is included in the project documentation for the existing design. This informa- tion includes project costs and data on current and projected traffic conditions for the existing design. Other data that may be needed can be generated by the VA team using traf- fic models (for impacts on travel time, VOC, and accident costs), engineering estimates (e.g., for initial, recurring, and annual costs of construction, maintenance, and operation of alternatives), and look-up tables that are part of Caltrans soft- ware (TVI International 1999, pp. 6.21–6.22). Caltrans has performed a review of its VA program in terms of returns on effort, project dollar savings, and resources required to conduct VA studies in relation to benefits. Key findings were as follows for 286 VA efforts completed between 2002 and 2009 (Tusup and Hays 2009, updated by input from Tusup in 2010 for this report): • The standard time devoted to a VA study is 6 days, ideally divided into two 3-day sessions. Five days is acceptable for smaller projects. • Three days or less is not acceptable for a proper VA study. Four days would be the minimum for small, local projects that are off the National Highway System. • Increasing the duration of the VA study can pay off in terms of both greater total project savings per VA study and the average savings realized for each day of the VA study effort. For example, although 3-day studies produced average construction savings of $2.81 million per VA study ($0.94 million per day of study), studies of 7 days or longer produced average savings per study of $18.45 million (roughly $2 million or more per day of VA effort). • The VA team leader must be a Certified Value Special- ist, with certification administered by SAVe Interna- tional® (“Certification Program” 2010). The VA team leader preferably has experience in the Caltrans VA process. Team leaders must be independent of the proj- ect and of its design team. • Qualified consultants may be used to conduct VA stud- ies on federal-aid projects. Consultants with indepen- dent VA affiliates can perform Ve on their own design, with independent team members not affiliated with the project. Caltrans has identified typical problems using VA, but none of the listed items relates to the benefit–cost component of the analysis. Most of the issues relate to management and logistics; for example, failure to plan enough time and bud- get to do the job right; impact of accelerated design, which

65 right-of-way acquisition in areas experiencing com- mercial and residential growth. • Road users experience lower direct costs of traffic dis- ruption resulting from construction in terms of travel- time costs, VOC, and costs of safety hazards. • Communities experience less adverse impacts on the local economy in terms of reduced business volume and temporary reductions in housing values resulting from construction-related congestion, noise, and impaired accessibility. • Project beneficiaries—road users, local citizens and businesses, the public at large—are able to realize sooner the economic benefits of the project because of the quicker completion of construction and the earlier opening of the highway to traffic. Within a discounted CBA, the discounted value of benefits is greater than would have been the case given a conventional con- struction time frame. • Various ancillary benefits also accrue; for example, in program scheduling and management (project comple- tions close existing commitments and enable schedulers to turn to new work); in reduced overhead and construc- tion management costs; and in gains in productivity and efficiency necessitated by the tighter deadlines and the closer interaction between design and construction. The HDR report to Mn/DOT acknowledges several risks in accelerated construction that are related to budget, proj- ect management/scheduling, engineering, and institutional arrangements (particularly those needed to prepare for actual construction; for example, right-of-way acquisition and util- ity work). The report discusses strategies to mitigate these risks, illustrated by the following examples (HDRHLB Decision economics Inc. 2006): • Budget risks can be mitigated through clear delineation of funding sources and arrangements, a clear and real- istic scope of work and project schedule, and a reliable cost accounting system with features that support effec- tive cost tracking and management. • Project management and scheduling risks can be miti- gated by adopting and applying an effective project scheduling and tracking system, employing good com- munication with affected parties, instituting quality assurance steps such as constructability reviews and a system of incentives and penalties governing time and cost performance, and building in scheduling flexibility to adjust to project circumstances. • engineering risks can be mitigated through good man- agement of the technical tasks and processes involved. Good practices include streamlining activities, main- taining good communications and coordination among stakeholders, organizing work tasks clearly within per- forming units, decentralizing personnel skills, strength- ening organizational capabilities as through training, and shifting quality assurance responsibilities to the contrac- tor to ensure its awareness of quality requirements. • Institutional risks in utility relocation can be mitigated through mechanisms such as securing up-front contracts for major utility relocation and providing incentives for timely completion of utility relocation. Risk-mitigation strategies in right-of-way acquisition include offering various incentives to property owners such as signing bonuses, increased nominal values of parcels, and lati- tude in negotiating offers. Agencies can also provide employees training in environmental stewardship of sensitive land uses affecting the parcels being acquired. Structure of the Economic Analysis The analyses of these economic and financial effects of accel- erated project delivery are summarized in Table 16. Costs, benefits, and other impacts of accelerated project delivery are structured in three categories: micro-economic impacts, which focus on transportation-related effects experienced by highway users; macro-economic impacts, which are experi- enced by the commercial and residential sectors of the local community; and agency-related impacts, which reflect the economic and the financial dimensions of changes in project costs owing to accelerated delivery. • Micro-economic impacts comprise changes in the respec- tive costs of travel time, VOC, crash or accident rates and severity, and environmental pollution resulting from vehicle emissions. • Macro-economic impacts comprise changes in commer- cial business levels and residential housing values within the affected community. • Agency impacts include effects on project-related costs and benefits in both an economic and financial dimension. The table considers two distinct time periods: • The period during project construction. The economic and financial effects identified in Table 16 are com- pared for a project with a more accelerated construc- tion schedule versus that with a more conventional timetable. • The period following completion of project construction. These project-driven transportation benefits, which reflect after-construction versus before-construction compari- sons of highway performance and road user costs, would have been achieved by the project regardless of construc- tion method. The key benefit of accelerated delivery by the agency is to attain these benefits earlier than would otherwise have been possible using more conventional construction approaches. The ROC 52 example was intended as a first step by Mn/DOT to develop generalized economic analysis proce- dures that could be applied to accelerated-delivery options for other highways. In addition to the costs and impacts cited in Table 16, Mn/DOT and its consultant also ensured that

66 (These distributions were estimated at the risk analysis workshop mentioned in the first bulleted item.) Model outputs can also be obtained as probabilistic estimates, although for clarity they are often reduced to mean values or to a limited set of distributions. Confidence intervals and decumulative distributions can also be obtained. Table 16 describes several components of the analysis con- ducted by Mn/DOT and its consultant, organized for use in this case example. In keeping with the objectives of this syn- thesis and the approaches that have been applied in other case examples, the focus of the remaining sections is specifically on transportation-related benefits and costs: that is, the agency- related economic costs and benefits and the micro-economic effects to highway users that are identified in Table 16. Project Characteristics and Design–Construction Options The ROC 52 project involved the design and reconstruction of approximately 11 miles of Trunk Highway 52, with the following work items: • Widening from 4 to 6 lanes along part of the project length; the following characteristics of good practice would be met in estimating costs and benefits of accelerated construction for ROC 52: • Transparency: Analytic methods and assumptions were reviewed by a multi-disciplinary panel of experts in economics, traffic engineering, planning, and local stakeholder interests. Reviews and discussions occurred at both a risk analysis workshop on the ROC 52 project and in subsequent meetings with Mn/DOT’s Office of Investment Management. Suggestions were incorpo- rated into the analysis described in subsequent sections. • Accuracy: Quantitative data were obtained from authori- tative public sources including the U.S. Census Bureau, the Congressional Budget Office, the Minnesota Depart- ment of employment and economic Development, the Minnesota State Demographic Center, and studies con- ducted or sponsored by FHWA. • Transferability: The ROC 52 example provided a practical laboratory for developing and organizing the data, methods, and assumptions of the economic analy- sis into a computerized procedure (Microsoft® Office excel workbook) that can be applied to other projects. • Risk Analysis: Because the economic analysis embod- ies forecasts in its estimates, the value of each model parameter is expressed as a probability distribution. Type of Im pact Period During Construction Period After Completion of Project Construction Micro- Econom ic Reduced Period of Disruption to Highway User o Travel tim e cost o Vehicle operating cost o Crash or accident cost o Environm ental emissions cost Im pacts of Congestion Relief o Travel tim e cost savings o Vehicle operating cost savings o Crash or accident cost savings o Environm ental emissions cost savings Macro- Econom ic Im pacts on Local Econom y Due to: o Construction spending o Reduced period of disrupted access to local businesses o Reduced period of construction effect on housing values Im pacts on Local Econom y Due to: o Incre me ntal spending for operations and maintenance o Im proved access to local businesses o Potentially changed housing values Agency Econom ic Effects o Reduced costs for time - dependent project ite ms (e.g., construction ma nagem ent, project overhead, traffic management) Financial and Budget Effects o Reduced budget expenditures for tim e-dependent project items o Reduced impact of inflation on project costs Economic Benefits to Public Provided through Agency’s Decision on Accelerated Construction o Earlier attainment of project’s benefits listed above Source: Mn/DOT ROC 52 study (HDR|HLB Decision Economics Inc. (2006), Summary Table 1). Additional explanations and clarifications drawn from the report text, and a separate delineation of agency economic and financial effects, have been inserted by the author. This table presents impacts relevant to Mn/DOT and to ROC 52 highway users; other impacts (e.g., financial savings to city of Rochester associated with lower loan costs resulting from accelerated project completion) are not included. TABLe 16 STRUCTURe OF eNGINeeRING eCONOMIC ANALYSIS DeSCRIBING IMPACTS OF PROJeCT ACCeLeRATION

67 • Construction or reconstruction of interchanges and frontage roads; • Construction of two new overpasses; • enhancements of ITS components; and • Other improvements; for example, in road surfacing, lighting, signage, pavement markings, noise and retain- ing walls, traffic signals, and detention ponds. Options to be considered in the economic analysis involved different construction-stage assumptions, including the use of design–build, to accelerate project completion. Mn/DOT and its consultant considered four options in establishing compara- tive estimates of time, cost, and impact: • Scenario 1, the Baseline: Conventional design and construction wherein the design stage spans approxi- mately 30 months (2.5 years) and the construction stage about 11 years, as estimated for the original project. • Scenario 2: Conventional design stage with same duration as that in Scenario 1, but with a shorter period of construction of 5 years with funding restrictions removed. • Scenario 3: Similar to Scenario 2, but with a further compressed construction duration of 3 years owing to some form of accelerated project delivery. • Scenario 4: Application of a design–build approach to conduct design and construction in parallel, leading to a combined duration of design and construction total- ing 3 years. Comparisons among these scenarios were structured as follows: • Scenario 2 compared with the Baseline Scenario 1; • Scenario 3 compared with the Baseline Scenario 1; and • Scenario 4 compared with the Baseline Scenario 1, and to Scenario 3. Costs were also estimated for a “No-Work” or “No-Build” option, which assumed no improvements to the highway during the analysis period. methods and measures Micro-Economic Highway User Impacts The beneficial impacts of project acceleration on highway users are measured in four categories of cost reduction: travel time, accidents or crashes, vehicle operation, and environ- mental emissions. The following sections discuss the factors included in calculations of each of these economic effects; mathematical formulas used in modeling computations are presented in the HDR report (HDRHLB Decision econom- ics Inc. 2006, pp. 10–15). Travel Time The total daily travel-time cost is computed at an aggregate level by vehicle type and peak versus off-peak period for each year of the analysis. In concept, the years may occur before construction (when congestion is affected by existing capacity prior to the project), during construction (when congestion is affected by work zone road occupancy and the duration of project work), and following construction (when congestion is presumably reduced owing to additional capacity provided by the project). Congestion effects are monetized in terms of total daily travel-time cost using a value-of-time calculation in each year that accounts for the following factors: • The value of time associated with each type of vehicle in each year, in $/hour; • A congestion premium expressed as the percent additional cost motorists are willing to pay to avoid congestion; • AADT by period of day, vehicle type, and year (number of vehicles); • The length of the project work zone in miles; and • The average speed through the work zone by period of day and year, in miles per hour. Accidents or Crashes Accident or crash costs are computed in terms of total daily accident-related costs by period of day, category of accident or crash, and year, accounting for these factors: • AADT by period of day, vehicle type, and year (number of vehicles); • The accident rate by period of day, category of accident, and year as estimated by FHWA for three categories of accidents: property-damage-only, injury, and fatal (accidents per some multiple of vehicle-miles); • The monetized cost of a crash as estimated by AASHTO for each category of accident by year; and • The length of the project work zone in miles. Vehicle Operation VOC is the monetized value of owning, operating, and maintaining a vehicle as affected by road characteristics and conditions. The model used by HDR for Mn/DOT considered VOC in two steps: • Constant-speed VOC for the following components: fuel consumption, oil consumption, vehicle maintenance and repair, tire wear, and roadway-related vehicle deprecia- tion estimated for a constant-speed condition. • excess VOC, comprising adjusted consumptions of the VOC components for the actual traffic, pavement, and speed-flow conditions anticipated to be encountered within the time frame of the analysis. The total daily VOC for each type of vehicle, period of day, and year of analysis was computed accounting for the following factors: • AADT by type of vehicle (auto, truck, or bus), period of day (peak or off-peak), and year of cost estimation within the analysis period (number of vehicles);

68 • A constant-speed VOC consumption rate and an excess VOC consumption rate for each VOC component: fuel, oil, tires, vehicle maintenance and repair, and road-related vehicle depreciation, estimated for each vehicle type, year, and (for excess VOC consumption) period of day; • Cost of each VOC component for each vehicle type and analysis year in terms of dollars per gallon of fuel, dollars per quart of oil, percentage of tire wear applied to total cost of each tire, percentage of average vehicle maintenance and repair cost, and percentage of vehicle- depreciable dollar value; • Length of the project work zone in miles; and • A pavement adjustment factor to reflect the influence of pavement condition on excess VOC. Vehicle Emissions Vehicle emissions costs are the monetized values of air pollution released daily by vehicles. The daily cost of air pollution emissions is computed for each combination of the following: type of emission, vehicle type, period of the day, and analysis year, using the following factors: • The rate of vehicle emission (in tons per numbers of vehicles) of each type of air pollution (hydrocarbons, carbon monoxide, and nitrogen oxides) by vehicle type, period of the day, and analysis year, obtained from FHWA emission-rate tables; • AADT by vehicle type, period of the day, and analysis year (number of vehicles); • Length of the project work zone in miles; and • The emission cost per ton of each of the three types of emissions, respectively, in each analysis year. Daily to Annual Conversion The four highway-user models described earlier yield results in cost per day. These cost results are converted to annual amounts using 365 days per year. Results for different project scenarios are also organized by whether the year corresponds to “during construction” or “post-construction” conditions. Role of Forecasting The four models above all depend on forecasts of key variables: • AADT is projected from baseline–year traffic volume using an average annual growth rate. Splits are applied to results in terms of peak versus off-peak periods of the day and vehicle type (autos, trucks, and buses). • Volume-capacity ratios (v/c) are estimated for peak and off-peak periods based on AADT, assumed truck- equivalency factors, and proposed work-zone configu- rations and capacities. • Average vehicle travel speeds for peak and off-peak periods are estimated using speed-flow relationships as a function of v/c and posted speed limits. Benefits of Accelerated Construction Completion The benefits of accelerated project completion are illus- trated in Figure 3, using the example of the congestion index (CI). (CI is a measure of urban traffic density on major metropolitan roadways. A value of CI greater than 1.0 indicates an undesirable level of congestion. This example is provided in the HDR report to suggest the gen- eral idea involved in calculating benefits of project accel- eration. Other measures can be used for the four road-user models described earlier; however, the basic idea would be the same.) In the absence of a project (the “No Work” scenario), the congestion index is assumed to increase with growth in traffic demand (AADT). A project to increase road capacity would reduce the congestion index, provid- ing a benefit to road users. In the upper chart of Figure 3, project construction extends through Duration 1. At project completion the level of con- gestion is reduced, providing a benefit corresponding to the area B1 between the two CI curves. The lower chart in Fig- ure 3 illustrates an accelerated project schedule that finishes project work within Duration 2, a shorter period of time. The resulting benefits are illustrated by areas B1 plus B2 between the two CI curves, providing an increased benefit. There may also be benefits owing to the shorter project duration in the second chart, but these need to be confirmed using the several models discussed earlier. For example, it would be reasonable to assume that total work-zone con- gestion would be less with Project Duration 2, leading to additional travel-time savings in accelerated-completion scenarios. Incremental costs resulting from work-zone crashes are also expected to be lower with shorter construc- tion duration, leading to greater safety benefits in terms of costs avoided. However, incremental VOC savings (espe- cially in the fuel consumption component) may not be posi- tive with shorter project duration, depending on the specific changes in speed and the number of stop-go cycles expe- rienced by traffic through the work zone. The actual varia- tions in road user costs that were computed across the four design–construction scenarios investigated are given later in this case. Project Costs to Agency Project costs for construction were estimated by HDR for each of the four scenarios defined earlier. Costs included direct project construction as well as several items that vary with project duration: temporary construction items, con- struction overhead, and construction management. Cost escalation (or inflation avoidance) was also included in the year-of-expenditure (Y.O.e.; that is, undiscounted) construc- tion cost estimates; this component was carried over into the discounted CBA as well. (To the extent that this adjustment reflects differential inflation effects in construction costs, it would be consistent with guidance by FHWA and others cited in chapter two that recommends constant-dollar esti- mates in the economic analysis.) The total estimated project costs are given in Table 17.

69 Time Congestion Index Project Duration 1 B1 Effect of Traffic Growth Assuming “No Work” Scenario Time Congestion Index B1 B2 Project Duration 2 Effect of Traffic Growth Assuming “No Work” Scenario FIGURE 3 Illustration of highway user cost savings due to project acceleration. Source: HDRHLB Decision Economics Inc. (2006), Figure 7, p. 11, with additional annotations by author. Risk Analysis The risk analysis conducted by Mn/DOT and its consultant was based on probabilistic input values of key variables. These ranges of values were then subjected to a Monte Carlo simulation, with results produced likewise as probabilistic distributions of costs and impacts. • Input values were specified by three data points: an anticipated median value (i.e., with 50% probability of being exceeded); a lower-10% value (with a 90% prob- ability of being exceeded); and an upper-10% value (with a 10% probability of being exceeded). These estimates were developed at a risk analysis workshop conducted at the Mn/DOT district office in Rochester before performing the economic analysis. The Monte Carlo procedure analyzed these data to infer a probabil- ity distribution for each input variable. • The Monte Carlo simulation was performed employing the analytic models discussed earlier and the probabilistic Scenario No. Scenario Cost, $ Millions 1 (Baseline) Conventional design (2.5 years) and construction (11 years) $371.4 2 Design (2.5 years) + reduced construction (5 years) $280.2 3 Design (2.5 years) + accelerated construction (3 years) $253.2 4 Design-build (3 years for design and construction) $236.0 Source: HDR|HLB Decision Economics Inc. (2006), Summary Figure 4, p. xii, and Figures 20 and 22, pp. 37 and 38. TABLe 17 eSTIMATeD YeAR-OF-exPeNDITURe PROJeCT COSTS BY SCeNARIO

70 scenarios, construction was scheduled to begin in 2005. Undiscounted or Y.O.e. costs were discounted to 2005 at a 4% discount rate. (Bear in mind that the ROC 52 project was serving as a case study for Mn/DOT and its consultant to develop this economic analysis for use in subsequent high- way projects. Costs were thus discounted to the then “pres- ent year” of 2005, the year in which the economic analysis was developed, rather than, say, to 2002 or 2003, which would have been a more typical “decision point” for considering ROC 52 construction options in an actual project-development setting.) Selected tables of results are presented here to illustrate different facets of the analysis results. The examples are for highway-user cost savings, relating to the models discussed earlier. Cost results are presented in Y.O.e. and total dis- counted amounts. Scenario comparisons are as discussed earlier: S2 versus S1 Baseline, S3 versus S1 Baseline, S4 versus S1 Baseline, and S4 versus S3, where “S” denotes Scenario. • Table 19 shows predicted cost savings to highway users by component of user cost for each scenario, and the incremental cost savings for each scenario compari- son. All costs in this table are in 20-year undiscounted Y.O.e. dollars. inputs. Results were produced as decumulative prob- ability curves; that is, curves indicating the probability that a predicted result will be exceeded by the actual result. These curves enabled Mn/DOT and HDR per- sonnel to identify the mean expected value, the value with 90% probability of being exceeded, and the value with 10% probability of being exceeded. Tables of results presented in a later section are based on mean- value results in each case. To illustrate how the risk analysis was structured, Table 18 presents selected input variables in terms of probabilistic data developed at the Mn/DOT workshop. Where different time periods are cited (e.g., hourly vs. monthly vs. annual costs), the analysis translates these to commensurate project amounts. Costs in Table 18 are undiscounted. Decision support Economic Analysis Results The economic analysis of the ROC 52 construction options was conducted for a 20-year analysis period, 2003 through 2022. Project design was assumed to start in 2003 across all four scenarios. For Scenario 4 (the design–build option), construction was also assumed to start in 2003; for other Input Variable or Factor Median Lower 10% Upper 10% Project Costs (2002 $) Total direct project construction costs $197,172,764 $197,172,764 $197,172,764 Monthly overhead costs (collocation office) $97,222 $77,778 $116,667 Monthly construction ma nagement costs $431,944 $345,556 $518,333 Warranty bond, cost per year $52,350 $52,350 $52,350 Road User Value of Time (2005 $) Aut o, $/hour $10.46 $8.00 $14.10 Heavy comm ercial vehicle, $/hour $19.39 $16.00 $24.00 Traffic Distribution Passenger cars and light trucks 93.5% 92.0% 95.0% Heavy comm ercial vehicles 6.5% 8.0% 5.0% Peak vs. Off-Peak Periods Length of the peak period, hours 5.0 4.0 6.0 Peak-hour traffic volum e, % of daily volum e 10.0% 8.0% 12.0% Peak-period traffic volum e, % of daily volume 65.0% 60.0% 70.0% Source: HDR|HLB Decision Economics Inc. (2006), pp. 26–29. TABLe 18 SeLeCTeD exAMPLeS OF RISK-ANALYSIS INPUT DATA

71 • Table 20 provides a summary of the micro-economic impacts expressed as highway-user cost savings in sev- eral ways simultaneously: – In 20-year undiscounted Y.O.e. dollars and in dis- counted 2005 dollars for the 20-year analysis period; – In two stages of the 20-year analysis: during construc- tion (reflecting work zone and temporary road effects) and after construction (reflecting improvements derived from the project), and for the two stages combined; – In a comparison of total highway-user cost savings as compared with the No-Work (or No-Build) option; and – In comparisons among scenarios: S2 versus S1, S3 versus S1, S4 versus S1, and S4 versus S3. • Table 21 illustrates the results of the risk analysis for the 20-year highway-user cost savings in undiscounted Y.O.e. dollars, organized by the four scenario comparisons. Conclusions of the ROC 52 Analysis Mn/DOT’s consultant drew several conclusions from this eco- nomic analysis that are listed here. Although this case example has focused on micro-economic transportation impacts that are reflected in highway-user cost savings, the full Mn/DOT analysis considered other economic impacts as well; that is, changes in residential housing values, increases in local com- mercial activity, and reduced construction overhead costs. The HDR report includes findings that reflect these other aspects of the economic analysis. However, when conservative analytic assessments of transportation impacts were called for (specifi- cally, to discuss the business case favoring use of design–build, as in Strategy 4 of the ROC 52 project), HDR focused solely on the highway-user cost savings, eliminating any possible double- counting among the other categories of economic impacts. This approach is consistent with the information presented in this case example. With this background, the overall conclusions as compiled in the HDR report are quoted as follows: By shortening the construction period and associated traf- fic disruption, project acceleration typically reduces highway user costs, and losses in housing values and retail sales in the immediate vicinity of the construction project. [This conclusion addresses the “During Construction” impacts.] By bringing the completion of highway projects sooner, proj- ect acceleration generates real economic value to highway users, avoiding congestion delays, highway accidents, and vehicle operating costs. The early completion of highway improvements also brings upturns in retail sales and home values sooner. [This conclusion addresses the “After Construction” impacts: both the generation of real benefits to road users, and the fact that benefits accrue to road users and the community earlier than they would with conventional construction.] Finally, through inflation avoidance and ancillary project cost savings, project acceleration is expected to reduce construction spending. Source: HDRHLB Decision economics Inc. (2006), pp. 46–47. resources required and other Information Consultant Assistance with Methodology Mn/DOT was assisted in this analysis by HDRHLB Deci- sion economics Inc. (HDR), which developed the methodol- ogy, performed the economic analysis, and wrote the report cited in this case. Mn/DOT participated in this development through activities such as study oversight, provision of data, and conduct of the risk analysis workshop. Development of Scenario Comparison Travel Tim e Accidents or Crashes Vehicle Operation Emissions Total Highway User Cost Savings Over No-Work (or No-Build) Option Scenario 1 (Baseline) ($27.7) $38.9 $80.8 $16.8 $108.8 Scenario 2 $58.4 $62.8 $190.1 $1.9 $313.1 Scenario 3 $80.1 $69.5 $220.9 ($2.2) $368.2 Scenario 4 $87.5 $75.9 $242.7 ($3.0) $403.1 Increm ental Highway User Cost Savings By Co mp aring Strategies Scenario 2 vs. Baseline $86.1 $23.9 $109.2 ($14.9) $204.3 Scenario 3 vs. Baseline $107.8 $30.6 $140.0 ($19.0) $259.4 Scenario 4 vs. Baseline $115.2 $37.0 $161.9 ($19.8) $294.3 Scenario 4 vs. Scenario 3 $7.4 $6.4 $21.8 ($0.8) $34.9 Source: HDR|HLB Decision Economics Inc. (2006), Figure 18, p. 35. Notes: Highway user costs are shown as negative cost savings. Round-off errors occur in some of the totals. TABLe 19 20-YeAR HIGHWAY USeR COST SAVINGS BY COST CATeGORY ($ MILLIONS, UNDISCOUNTeD)

72 • Development of a model for analyzing project- acceleration benefits within a risk-analysis frame- work, addressing benefits in four areas: budget, finan- cial, micro-economic impacts (the highway-user cost savings), and macro-economic impacts. • Conduct of the risk-analysis workshop with Mn/DOT project stakeholders. the analysis involved the following tasks (HDRHLB Deci- sion economics Inc. 2006, p. 45): • Review of the available literature related to the benefits of project acceleration, and identification of local, state, national, and international data sources for relevant economic indicators. All Estimates for 2003–2022 $ Millions, Undiscounted Y.O.E. $ Millions, Discounted to 2005 Scenario Comparison During Project After Project Total During Project After Project Total Highway User Cost Savings Over No-Work (or No-Build) Option Scenario 1 (Baseline) ($123.7) $232.5 $108.8 ($90.8) $98.0 $7.2 Scenario 2 ($52.8) $366.0 $313.1 ($46.7) $182.2 $135.4 Scenario 3 ($33.0) $401.2 $368.2 ($31.3) $210.7 $179.3 Scenario 4 ($29.8) $432.9 $403.1 ($31.5) $239.6 $208.1 Incremental Highway User Cost Savings By Comparing Strategies Scenario 2 vs. Baseline $70.9 $133.4 $204.3 $44.1 $84.1 $128.2 Scenario 3 vs. Baseline $90.7 $168.7 $259.4 $59.5 $112.6 $172.1 Scenario 4 vs. Baseline $93.9 $200.4 $294.3 $59.3 $141.5 $200.9 Scenario 4 vs. Scenario 3 $3.2 $31.7 $34.9 ($0.2) $28.9 $28.7 Source: HDR|HLB Decision Economics Inc. (2006), Table 24, p. 44. Notes: Y.O.E. = Year-of-Expenditure. Highway user costs (shown as negative cost savings in the “During Project” column) reflect traffic disruption due to construction. Highway user cost savings after the project reflect the resulting improvement in traffic flow. Round-off errors occur in some of the totals. TABLe 20 20-YeAR HIGHWAY USeR COST SAVINGS DURING AND AFTeR PROJeCT CONSTRUCTION ($ MILLIONS) All Esti mates for 2003–2022 $ Millions, Undiscounted Y.O.E. $ Millions, Discounted to 2005 Scenario Comparison Mean Expected Value 90% Probability Exceeding 10% Probability Exceeding Mean Expected Value 90% Probability Exceeding 10% Probability Exceeding Scenario 2 vs. Baseline $204.3 $168.7 $267.3 $128.2 $106.2 $167.1 Scenario 3 vs. Baseline $259.4 $215.5 $335.2 $172.1 $143.6 $220.9 Scenario 4 vs. Baseline $294.3 $244.5 $380.9 $200.9 $167.4 $259.2 Scenario 4 vs. Scenario 3 $34.9 $28.9 $45.9 $28.7 $23.7 $38.4 Source: HDR|HLB Decision Economics Inc. (2006), Table 25, p. 45. Note: Y.O.E. = Year-of-Expenditure. “x% Probability Exceeding” means that actual savings have an x-percent probability of exceeding the predicted cost savings shown. TABLe 21 RISK ANALYSIS ReSULTS FOR 20-YeAR HIGHWAY USeR COST SAVINGS ($ MILLIONS)

73 cycle of a highway facility. each case, however, has focused on a particular application and the practices and viewpoints of a particular agency. The next chapter steps back from the set of cases to take a broader look at what economic methods mean to highway investment decisions overall. Chapter four addresses several important issues: the value of economic analyses, the role of economic analyses in strengthening agency decision making, the level of effort in using economic methods, factors favoring success, and useful resources avail- able. There are also discussions of the relationship between economic analysis and performance measurement, the role of reporting and communication, and ongoing and emerging areas of application. • Incorporation of expert panel comments within revi- sions to the analytic model. • Conduct of the analysis, including the Monte Carlo simulations used in the risk analysis. • Preparation of the report describing the analysis and results. Case Closure The several cases in this chapter have provided many exam- ples of how engineering economic methods and data can be applied to investment decisions at a number of points in the life

TRB’s National Cooperative Highway Research Program (NCHRP) Synthesis 424: Engineering Economic Analysis Practices for Highway Investment explores how U.S. transportation agencies have applied engineering economics--benefit–cost analyses and similar procedures--to decisions on highway investments.

TR News 292: May-June 2014 includes an article about the report.

READ FREE ONLINE

Welcome to OpenBook!

You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

Show this book's table of contents , where you can jump to any chapter by name.

...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter .

Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

View our suggested citation for this chapter.

Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

Get Email Updates

Do you enjoy reading reports from the Academies online for free ? Sign up for email notifications and we'll let you know about new publications in your areas of interest when they're released.

Microsoft

Game Central

Addressing employee burnout: Are you solving the right problem?

The COVID-19 pandemic has accelerated and exacerbated long-standing corporate challenges to employee health and well-being , and in particular employee mental health. 1 When used in this article, “mental health” is a term inclusive of positive mental health and the full range of mental, substance use, and neurological conditions. This has resulted in reports of rapidly rising rates of burnout 2 When used in this article, “burnout” and “burnout symptoms” refer to work-driven burnout symptoms (per sidebar “What is burnout?”). around the world (see sidebar “What is burnout?”).

About the authors

This article is a collaborative effort by Jacqueline Brassey , Erica Coe , Martin Dewhurst, Kana Enomoto , Renata Giarola, Brad Herbig, and Barbara Jeffery , representing the views of the McKinsey Health Institute.

Many employers have responded by investing more into mental health and well-being than ever before. Across the globe, four in five HR leaders report that mental health and well-being is a top priority for their organization. 3 McKinsey Health Institute Employee Mental Health and Wellbeing Survey, 2022: n (employee) = 14,509; n (HR decision maker) = 1,389. Many companies offer a host of wellness benefits such as yoga, meditation app subscriptions, well-being days, and trainings on time management and productivity. In fact, it is estimated that nine in ten organizations around the world offer some form of wellness program. 4 Charlotte Lieberman, “What wellness programs don’t do for workers,” Harvard Business Review , August 14, 2019.

As laudable as these efforts are, we have found that many employers focus on individual-level interventions that remediate symptoms, rather than resolve the causes of employee burnout. 5 Anna-Lisa Eilerts et al., “Evidence of workplace interventions—A systematic review of systematic reviews,” International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health , 2019, Volume 16, Number 19. Employing these types of interventions may lead employers to overestimate the impact of their wellness programs and benefits 6 Katherine Baicker et al., “Effect of a workplace wellness program on employee health and economic outcomes: A randomized clinical trial,” JAMA , 2019, Volume 321, Number 15; erratum published in JAMA , April 17, 2019. and to underestimate the critical role of the workplace in reducing burnout and supporting employee mental health and well-being. 7 Pascale M. Le Blanc, et al., “Burnout interventions: An overview and illustration,” in Jonathan R. B. Halbesleben’s Handbook of Stress and Burnout in Health Care , New York, NY: Nova Science Publishers, 2008; Peyman Adibi et al., “Interventions for physician burnout: A systematic review of systematic reviews,” International Journal of Preventive Medicine , July 2018, Volume 9, Number 1.

What is burnout?

According to the World Health Organization, burnout is an occupational phenomenon. It is driven by a chronic imbalance between job demands 1 Job demands are physical, social, or organizational aspects of the job that require sustained physical or mental effort and are therefore associated with certain physiological and psychological costs—for example, work overload and expectations, interpersonal conflict, and job insecurity. Job resources are those physical, social, or organizational aspects of the job that may do any of the following: (a) be functional in achieving work goals; (b) reduce job demands and the associated physiological and psychological costs; (c) stimulate personal growth and development such as feedback, job control, social support (Wilmar B. Schaufeli and Toon W. Taris, “A critical review of the job demands-resources model: Implications for improving work and health,” from Georg F. Bauer and Oliver Hämmig’s Bridging Occupational, Organizational and Public Health: A Transdisciplinary Approach , first edition, Dordrecht, Netherlands: Springer, 2014). (for example, workload pressure and poor working environment) and job resources (for example, job autonomy and supportive work relationships). It is characterized by extreme tiredness, reduced ability to regulate cognitive and emotional processes, and mental distancing. Burnout has been demonstrated to be correlated with anxiety and depression, a potential predictor of broader mental health challenges. 2 Previous meta-analytic findings demonstrate moderate positive correlations of burnout with anxiety and depression—suggesting that anxiety and depression are related to burnout but represent different constructs (Katerina Georganta et al., “The relationship between burnout, depression, and anxiety: A systematic review and meta-analysis,” Frontiers in Psychology , March 2019, Volume 10, Article 284). When used in this article, burnout does not imply a clinical condition.

Research shows that, when asked about aspects of their jobs that undermine their mental health and well-being, 8 Paula Davis, Beating Burnout at Work: Why Teams Hold the Secret to Well-Being and Resilience , Philadelphia, PA: Wharton School Press, 2021. employees frequently cite the feeling of always being on call, unfair treatment, unreasonable workload, low autonomy, and lack of social support. 9 Jennifer Moss, The Burnout Epidemic: The Rise of Chronic Stress and How We Can Fix It , Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press, 2021. Those are not challenges likely to be reversed with wellness programs. In fact, decades of research suggest that interventions targeting only individuals are far less likely to have a sustainable impact on employee health than systemic solutions, including organizational-level interventions. 10 Hanno Hoven et al., “Effects of organisational-level interventions at work on employees’ health: A systematic review,” BMC Public Health , 2014, Volume 14, Number 135.

Since many employers aren’t employing a systemic approach, many have weaker improvements in burnout and employee mental health and well-being than they would expect, given their investments.

Organizations pay a high price for failure to address workplace factors 11 Gunnar Aronsson et al., “A systematic review including meta-analysis of work environment and burnout symptoms,” BMC Public Health , 2017, Volume 17, Article 264. that strongly correlate with burnout, 12 Sangeeta Agrawal and Ben Wigert, “Employee burnout, part 1: The 5 main causes,” Gallup, July 12, 2018. such as toxic behavior. 13 The high cost of a toxic workplace culture: How culture impacts the workforce — and the bottom line , Society for Human Resource Management, September 2019. A growing body of evidence, including our research in this report, sheds light on how burnout and its correlates may lead to costly organizational issues such as attrition. 14 Caio Brighenti et al., “Why every leader needs to worry about toxic culture,” MIT Sloan Management Review, March 16, 2022. Unprecedented levels of employee turnover—a global phenomenon we describe as the Great Attrition —make these costs more visible. Hidden costs to employers also include absenteeism, lower engagement, and decreased productivity. 15 Eric Garton, “Employee burnout is a problem with the company, not the person,” Harvard Business Review , April 6, 2017.

The McKinsey Health Institute: Join us!

The McKinsey Health Institute (MHI) is an enduring, non-profit-generating global entity within McKinsey. MHI strives to catalyze actions across continents, sectors, and communities to achieve material improvements in health, empowering people to lead their best possible lives. MHI is fostering a strong network of organizations committed to this aspiration, including employers globally who are committed to supporting the health of their workforce and broader communities.

MHI has a near-term focus on the urgent priority of mental health, with launch of a flagship initiative around employee mental health and well-being. By convening leading employers, MHI aims to collect global data, synthesize insights, and drive innovation at scale. Through collaboration, we can truly make a difference, learn together, and co-create solutions for workplaces to become enablers of health—in a way that is good for business, for employees, and for the communities in which they live.

To stay updated about MHI’s initiative on employee mental health and well-being sign up at McKinsey.com/mhi/contact-us .

In this article, we discuss findings of a recent McKinsey Health Institute (MHI)  (see sidebar “The McKinsey Health Institute: Join us!”) global survey that sheds light on frequently overlooked workplace factors underlying employee mental health and well-being in organizations around the world. We conclude by teeing up eight questions for reflection along with recommendations on how organizations can address employee mental-health and well-being challenges by taking a systemic approach focused on changing the causes rather than the symptoms of poor outcomes. While there is no well-established playbook, we suggest employers can and should respond through interventions focused on prevention rather than remediation.

We are seeing persistent burnout challenges around the world

To better understand the disconnection between employer efforts and rising employee mental-health and well-being challenges (something we have observed  since the start of the pandemic ), between February and April 2022 we conducted a global survey of nearly 15,000 employees and 1,000 HR decision makers in 15 countries. 16 Argentina, Australia, Brazil, China, Egypt, France, Germany, India, Japan, Mexico, South Africa, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom, and the United States. The combined population of the selected countries correspond to approximately 70 percent of the global total.

The workplace dimensions assessed in our survey included toxic workplace behavior, sustainable work, inclusivity and belonging, supportive growth environment, freedom from stigma, organizational commitment, leadership accountability, and access to resources. 17 The associations of all these factors with employee health and well-being have been extensively explored in the academic literature. That literature heavily informed the development of our survey instrument. We have psychometrically validated this survey across 15 countries including its cross-cultural factorial equivalence. For certain outcome measures we collaborated with academic experts who kindly offered us their validated scales including the Burnout Assessment Tool (BAT), the Distress Screener, and the Adaptability Scale referenced below. Those dimensions were analyzed against four work-related outcomes—intent to leave, work engagement, job satisfaction, and organization advocacy—as well as four employee mental-health outcomes—symptoms of anxiety, burnout, depression, and distress. 18 Instruments used were the Burnout Assessment Tool (Steffie Desart et al., User manual - Burnout assessment tool [BAT ] , - Version 2.0, July 2020) (burnout symptoms); Distress Screener (4DSQ; JR Anema et al., “Validation study of a distress screener,” Journal of Occupational Rehabilitation , 2009, Volume 19) (distress); GAD-2 assessment (Priyanka Bhandari et al., “Using Generalized Anxiety Disorder-2 [GAD-2] and GAD-7 in a primary care setting,” Cureus , May 20, 2021, Volume 12, Number 5) (anxiety symptoms); and the PHQ-2 assessment (Patient Health Questionnaire [PHQ-9 & PHQ-2], American Psychological Association) (depression symptoms). Individual adaptability was also assessed 19 In this article, “adaptability” refers to the “affective adaptability” which is one sub-dimension of The Adaptability Scale instrument (Michel Meulders and Karen van Dam, “The adaptability scale: Development, internal consistency, and initial validity evidence,” European Journal of Psychological Assessment , 2020, Volume 37, Number 2). (see sidebar “What we measured”).

What we measured

Workplace factors assessed in our survey included:

  • Toxic workplace behavior: Employees experience interpersonal behavior that leads them to feel unvalued, belittled, or unsafe, such as unfair or demeaning treatment, noninclusive behavior, sabotaging, cutthroat competition, abusive management, and unethical behavior from leaders or coworkers.
  • Inclusivity and belonging: Organization systems, leaders, and peers foster a welcoming and fair environment for all employees to be themselves, find connection, and meaningfully contribute.
  • Sustainable work: Organization and leaders promote work that enables a healthy balance between work and personal life, including a manageable workload and work schedule.
  • Supportive growth environment: Managers care about employee opinions, well-being, and satisfaction and provide support and enable opportunities for growth.
  • Freedom from stigma and discrimination: Freedom from the level of shame, prejudice, or discrimination employees perceive toward people with mental-health or substance-use conditions.
  • Organizational accountability: Organization gathers feedback, tracks KPIs, aligns incentives, and measures progress against employee health goals.
  • Leadership commitment: Leaders consider employee mental health a top priority, publicly committing to a clear strategy to improve employee mental health.
  • Access to resources: Organization offers easy-to-use and accessible resources that fit individual employee needs related to mental health. 1 Including adaptability and resilience-related learning and development resources.

Health outcomes assessed in our survey included:

  • Burnout symptoms: An employee’s experience of extreme tiredness, reduced ability to regulate cognitive and emotional processes, and mental distancing (Burnout Assessment Tool). 2 Burnout Assessment Tool, Steffie Desart et al., “User manual - Burnout assessment tool (BAT), - Version 2.0,” July 2020.
  • Distress: An employee experiencing a negative stress response, often involving negative affect and physiological reactivity (4DSQ Distress Screener). 3 Distress screener, 4DSQ; JR Anema et al., “Validation study of a distress screener,” Journal of Occupational Rehabilitation , 2009, Volume 19.
  • Depression symptoms: An employee having little interest or pleasure in doing things, and feeling down, depressed, or hopeless (PHQ-2 Screener). 4 Kurt Kroenke et al., “The patient health questionnaire-2: Validity of a two-item depression screener,” Medical Care , November 2003, Volume 41, Issue 11.
  • Anxiety symptoms: An employee’s feelings of nervousness, anxiousness, or being on edge, and not being able to stop or control worrying (GAD-2 Screener). 5 Kurt Kroenke et al., “Anxiety disorders in primary care: Prevalence, impairment, comorbidity, and detection,” Annals of Internal Medicine , March 6, 2007, Volume 146, Issue 5.

Work-related outcomes assessed in our survey included:

  • Intent to leave: An employee’s desire to leave the organization in which they are currently employed in the next three to six months.
  • Work engagement: An employee’s positive motivational state of high energy combined with high levels of dedication and a strong focus on work.
  • Organizational advocacy: An employee’s willingness to recommend or endorse their organization as a place to work to friends and relatives.
  • Work satisfaction: An employee’s level of contentment or satisfaction with their current job.

Our survey pointed to a persistent disconnection between how employees and employers perceive mental health and well-being in organizations. We see an average 22 percent gap between employer and employee perceptions—with employers consistently rating workplace dimensions associated with mental health and well-being more favorably than employees. 20 Our survey did not link employers and employees’ responses. Therefore, these numbers are indicative of a potential gap that could be found within companies.

In this report—the first of a broader series on employee mental health from the McKinsey Health Institute—we will focus on burnout, its workplace correlates, and implications for leaders. On average, one in four employees surveyed report experiencing burnout symptoms. 21 Represents global average of respondents experiencing burnout symptoms (per items from Burnout Assessment Tool) sometimes, often, or always. These high rates were observed around the world and among various demographics (Exhibit 1), 22 Our survey findings demonstrate small but statistically significant differences between men and women, with women reporting higher rates of burnout symptoms (along with symptoms of distress, depression, and anxiety). Differences between demographic variables across countries will be discussed in our future publications. and are consistent with global trends. 23 Ashley Abramson, “Burnout and stress are everywhere,” Monitor on Psychology , January 1, 2022, Volume 53, Number 1.

So, what is behind pervasive burnout challenges worldwide? Our research suggests that employers are overlooking the role of the workplace in burnout and underinvesting in systemic solutions.

Employers tend to overlook the role of the workplace in driving employee mental health and well-being, engagement, and performance

In all 15 countries and across all dimensions assessed, toxic workplace behavior was the biggest predictor of burnout symptoms and intent to leave by a large margin 24 Measured as a function of predictive power of the dimensions assessed; predictive power was estimated based on share of outcome variability associated with each dimension; based on regression models applied to cross-sectional data (that is, measured at one point in time), rather than longitudinal data (that is, measured over time); causal relationships have not been established. —predicting more than 60 percent of the total global variance. For positive outcomes (including work engagement, job satisfaction, and organization advocacy), the impact of factors assessed was more distributed—with inclusivity and belonging, supportive growth environment, sustainable work, and freedom from stigma predicting most outcomes (Exhibit 2).

In all 15 countries and across all dimensions assessed, toxic workplace behavior had the biggest impact predicting burnout symptoms and intent to leave by a large margin.

The danger of toxic workplace behavior—and its impact on burnout and attrition

Across the 15 countries in the survey, toxic workplace behavior is the single largest predictor of negative employee outcomes, including burnout symptoms (see sidebar “What is toxic workplace behavior?”). One in four employees report experiencing high rates of toxic behavior at work. At a global level, high rates were observed across countries, demographic groups—including gender, organizational tenure, age, virtual/in-person work, manager and nonmanager roles—and industries. 25 Differences between demographic variables across countries will be discussed in our future articles.

What is toxic workplace behavior?

Toxic workplace behavior is interpersonal behavior that leads to employees feeling unvalued, belittled, or unsafe, such as unfair or demeaning treatment, non-inclusive behavior, sabotaging, cutthroat competition, abusive management, and unethical behavior from leaders or coworkers. Selected questions from this dimension include agreement with the statements “My manager ridicules me,” “I work with people who belittle my ideas,” and “My manager puts me down in front of others.”

Toxic workplace behaviors are a major cost for employers—they are heavily implicated in burnout, which correlates with intent to leave and ultimately drives attrition. In our survey, employees who report experiencing high levels of toxic behavior 26 “High” represents individuals in the top quartile of responses and “low” represents individuals in the bottom quartile of responses. at work are eight times more likely to experience burnout symptoms (Exhibit 3). In turn, respondents experiencing burnout symptoms were six times more likely to report they intend to leave their employers in the next three to six months (consistent with recent data pointing to toxic culture as the single largest predictor of resignation during the Great Attrition, ten times more predictive than compensation alone 27 Charles Sull et al., “Toxic culture is driving the Great Resignation,” MIT Sloan Management Review, January 11, 2022. and associated with meaningful organizational costs 28 Rasmus Hougaard, “To stop the Great Resignation, we must fight dehumanization at work,” Potential Project, 2022. ). The opportunity for employers is clear. Studies show that intent to leave may correlate with two- to three-times higher 29 Bryan Bohman et al., “Estimating institutional physician turnover attributable to self-reported burnout and associated financial burden: A case study,” BMC Health Services Research , November 27, 2018, Volume 18, Number 1. rates of attrition; conservative estimates of the cost of replacing employees range from one-half to two times their annual salary. Even without accounting for costs associated with burnout—including organizational commitment 30 Michael Leiter and Christina Maslach, “The impact of interpersonal environment on burnout and organizational commitment,” Journal of Organizational Behavior , October 1988, Volume 9, Number 4. and higher rates of sick leave and absenteeism 31 Arnold B. Bakker et al., “Present but sick: A three-wave study on job demands, presenteeism and burnout,” Career Development International , 2009, Volume 14, Number 1. —the business case for addressing it is compelling. The alternative—not addressing it—can lead to a downward spiral in individual and organizational performance. 32 Arnold B. Bakker et al., “Present but sick: A three-wave study on job demands, presenteeism and burnout,” Career Development International , 2009, Volume 14, Number 1.

Individuals’ resilience and adaptability skills may help but do not compensate for the impact of a toxic workplace

Toxic behavior is not an easy challenge to address. Some employers may believe the solution is simply training people to become more resilient.

There is merit in investing in adaptability and resiliency skill building . Research indicates that employees who are more adaptable tend to have an edge in managing change and adversity. 33 Karen van Dam, “Employee adaptability to change at work: A multidimensional, resource-based framework,” from The Psychology of Organizational Change: Viewing Change from the Employee’s Perspective , Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 2013; Jacqueline Brassey et al., Advancing Authentic Confidence Through Emotional Flexibility: An Evidence-Based Playbook of Insights, Practices and Tools to Shape Your Future , second edition, Morrisville, NC: Lulu Press, 2019; B+B Vakmedianet B.V. Zeist, Netherlands (to be published Q3 2022). We see that edge reflected in our survey findings: adaptability acts as a buffer 34 Estimated buffering effect illustrated in Exhibit 4. to the impact of damaging workplace factors (such as toxic behaviors), while magnifying the benefit of supportive workplace factors (such as a supportive growth environment) (Exhibit 4). In a recent study, employees engaging in adaptability training experienced three times more improvement in leadership dimensions and seven times more improvement in self-reported well-being than those in the control group. 35 McKinsey’s People and Organization Performance - Adaptability Learning Program; multirater surveys showed improvements in adaptability outcomes, including performance in role, sustainment of well-being, successfully adapting to unplanned circumstances and change, optimism, development of new knowledge and skills; well-being results were based on self-reported progress as a result of the program.

However, employers who see building resilience and adaptability skills in individuals as the sole solution to toxic behavior and burnout challenges are misguided. Here is why.

Individual skills cannot compensate for unsupportive workplace factors. When it comes to the effect of individual skills, leaders should be particularly cautious not to misinterpret “favorable” outcomes (for example, buffered impact of toxic behaviors across more adaptable employees) as absence of underlying workplace issues that should be addressed. 36 Tomas Chamorro-Premuzic, “To prevent burnout, hire better bosses,” Harvard Business Review , August 23, 2019.

Also, while more adaptable employees are better equipped to work in poor environments, they are less likely to tolerate them. In our survey, employees with high adaptability were 60 percent more likely to report intent to leave their organization if they experienced high levels of toxic behavior at work than those with low adaptability (which may possibly relate to a higher level of self-confidence 37 Brassey et al. found that as a result of a learning program, employees who developed emotional flexibility skills, a concept related to affective adaptability but also strongly linked to connecting with purpose, developed a higher self-confidence over time; Jacqueline Brassey et al., “Emotional flexibility and general self-efficacy: A pilot training intervention study with knowledge workers,” PLOS ONE , October 14, 2020, Volume 15, Number 10. ). Therefore, relying on improving employee adaptability without addressing broader workplace factors puts employers at an even higher risk of losing some of its most resilient, adaptable employees.

Employees with high adaptability were 60 percent more likely to report intent to leave their organization if they experienced high levels of toxic behavior at work than those with low adaptability.

What this means for employers: Why organizations should take a systemic approach to improving employee mental health and well-being

We often think of employee mental health, well-being, and burnout as a personal problem. That’s why most companies have responded to symptoms by offering resources focused on individuals such as wellness programs.

However, the findings in our global survey and research are clear. Burnout is experienced by individuals, but the most powerful drivers of burnout are systemic organizational imbalances across job demands and job resources. So, employers can and should view high rates of burnout as a powerful warning sign that the organization—not the individuals in the workforce—needs to undergo meaningful systematic change.

Employers can and should view high rates of burnout as a powerful warning sign that the organization—not the individuals in the workforce—needs to undergo meaningful systematic change.

Taking a systemic approach means addressing both toxic workplace behavior and redesigning work to be inclusive, sustainable, and supportive of individual learning and growth, including leader and employee adaptability skills. It means rethinking organizational systems, processes, and incentives to redesign work, job expectations, and team environments.

As an employer, you can’t “yoga” your way out of these challenges. Employers who try to improve burnout without addressing toxic behavior are likely to fail. Our survey shows that improving all other organization factors assessed (without addressing toxic behavior) does not meaningfully improve reported levels of burnout symptoms. Yet, when toxic behavior levels are low, each additional intervention contributes to reducing negative outcomes and increasing positive ones.

The interactive graphic shows the estimated interplay between the drivers and outcomes, based on our survey data (Exhibit 5).

Taking a preventative, systemic approach—focused on addressing the roots of the problem (as opposed to remediating symptoms)—is hard. But the upside for employers is a far greater ability to attract and retain valuable talent over time.

The good news: Although there are no silver bullets, there are opportunities for leaders to drive material change

We see a parallel between the evolution of global supply chains and talent. Many companies optimized supply chains for “just in time” delivery, and talent was optimized to drive operational efficiency and effectiveness. As supply chains come under increasing pressure, many companies recognize the need to redesign and optimize supply chains for resilience and sustainability, and the need to take an end-to-end approach to the solutions. The same principles apply to talent.

We acknowledge that the factors associated with improving employee mental health and well-being (including organizational-, team-, and individual-level factors) are numerous and complex. And taking a whole-systems approach is not easy.

Would you like to learn more about the McKinsey Health Institute ?

Despite the growing momentum toward better employee mental health and well-being (across business and academic communities), we’re still early on the journey. We don’t yet have sufficient evidence to conclude which interventions work most effectively—or a complete understanding of why they work and how they affect return on investment.

That said, efforts to mobilize the organization to rethink work—in ways that are compatible with both employee and employer goals—are likely to pay off in the long term. To help spark that conversation in your organization, we offer eight targeted questions and example strategies with the potential to address some of the burnout-related challenges discussed in this article.

Do we treat employee mental health and well-being as a strategic priority?

This is fundamental to success. When a large organization achieved a 7 percent reduction in employee burnout rates (compared with an 11 percent increase in the national average within the industry over the same period), the CEO believed that leadership and sustained attention from the highest level of the organization were the “key to making progress.” 38 John H. Noseworthy and Tait D Shanafelt, “Executive leadership and physician well‐being: Nine organizational strategies to promote engagement and reduce burnout,” Mayo Clinic Proceedings , January 2017, Volume 92, Number 1. Senior executives recognized employee mental health and well-being as a strategic priority. Executives publicly acknowledged the issues and listened to employee needs through a wide range of formats—including town halls, workshops, and employee interviews (our research suggests that leaders are not listening to their people  nearly enough). They prioritized issues and defined clear, time-bound measurable goals around them—with a standardized measure of burnout being given equal importance to other key performance metrics (financial metrics, safety/quality, employee turnover, and customer satisfaction). Although anonymous at the level of the individual, results were aggregated at division/department level to allow executive leadership to focus attention and resources where they were most needed. 39 Liselotte Dyrbye et al., “Physician burnout: Contributors, consequences and solutions,” Journal of Internal Medicine , 2018, Volume 283, Number 6. This example highlights how CEOs have the ability to create meaningful change through listening to employees and prioritizing strategies to reduce burnout.

Do we effectively address toxic behaviors?

Eliminating toxic workplace behavior is not an easy task. Organizations that tackle toxic behavior effectively deploy a set of integrated work practices  to confront the problem, 40 Robert I. Sutton, The No Asshole Rule: Building a Civilized Workplace and Surviving One That Isn’t , first edition, New York, NY: Business Plus, 2010. and see treatment of others as an integral part of assessing an employee’s performance. Manifestations of toxic behavior 41 “Why every leader,” 2022. are flagged, repeat offenders either change or leave, and leaders take time  to become aware of the impact their behavior has on others. If you lead part of an organization, looking at your own behaviors, and what you tolerate in your own organization, is a good place to start. 42 “ Author Talks: How to handle your work jerk ,” March 29, 2022.

Leaders with higher self-regulation may be better, less toxic leaders

Research shows that leaders’ development of self-regulation increases followers’ ratings of their effectiveness and is associated with higher team financial performance as well as a higher final team grade compared with a control group. The benefits of self-regulation also improved leaders’ development of task-relevant competencies. 1 Robin Martin and JooBee Yeow, “The role of self-regulation in developing leaders: A longitudinal field experiment,” Leadership Quarterly , October 2013, Volume 24, Number 5. Furthermore, building employees’ resilience and adaptability  skills leads to a higher sense of agency and self-efficacy, 2 Jacqueline Brassey et al., “Emotional flexibility and general self-efficacy: A pilot training intervention study with knowledge workers,” PLOS ONE , October 14, 2020, Volume 15, Number 10; and Jacqueline Brassey et al., Advancing Authentic Confidence Through Emotional Flexibility: An Evidence-Based Playbook of Insights, Practices and Tools to Shape Your Future , second edition, Morrisville, NC: Lulu Press, 2019; B+B Vakmedianet B.V. Zeist, Netherlands (to be published Q3 2022). which is related to reduced burnout and improved performance. 3 Charles Benight et al., “Associations between job burnout and self-efficacy: A meta-analysis,” Anxiety, Stress, & Coping , 2016, Volume 29, Issue 4; and Alex Stajkovic, “Self-efficacy and work-related performance: A meta-analysis,” Psychological Bulletin , 1998, Volume 124, Number 2.

Another component of eliminating toxic behavior is cultivating supportive, psychologically safe work environments , where toxic behaviors are less likely to spread  across the organization. 43 Annie McKee, “Neutralize your toxic boss,” Harvard Business Review , September 24, 2008. Effective leaders know that emotional contagion 44 John T. Cacioppo et al., Emotional Contagion , Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1994. may go both ways: displaying vulnerability and compassion  fuels more compassionate teams; displaying toxic behavior fuels more toxic teams. 45 Michael Housman and Dylan Minor, Toxic workers , Harvard Business School working paper, No. 16-057, October 2015 (revised November 2015). There are two caveats: toxic behavior may not be intentional—particularly if individuals are not equipped to respond with calm  and compassion under pressure—and regardless of intent, toxic behavior spreads faster and wider than good behavior. 46 “To prevent burnout,” 2019. To prevent unintentional dissemination of toxic behaviors, role modeling from adaptable , self-regulating, compassionate leaders may help (see sidebar “Leaders with higher self-regulation may be better, less toxic leaders”).

Do we create inclusive work environments?

Most leaders recognize the established associations between performance and inclusion , but inclusion does not happen by accident . Inclusion is a multifaceted construct that must be addressed comprehensively and proactively. Most companies define inclusion too narrowly and thus address it too narrowly as well. Over the past three years, we’ve broadened our perspective  on how to create truly inclusive workplaces and developed a modern inclusion model . The model includes 17 practices (based on frequency of desired behaviors) and six outcomes (based on perceptions of effectiveness). Each practice falls into one of three relationships that shape workplace inclusion: organizational systems, leaders, and peers/teammates.

The 17 inclusive-workplace practices , when done consistently well, drive workplace inclusion and equity for all employees by providing clarity into actions that matter. For example, among employees working in hybrid models , work–life support was the top practice employees desired improvements on—with nearly half of employees recommending prioritizing policies that support flexibility—including extended parental leave, flexible hours, and work-from-home policies.

A truly inclusive workplace implements systems that minimize conscious and unconscious bias , allowing employees to express themselves and connect with each other. It also features leaders who not only advocate for team members and treat them impartially but also uphold and support all organizational systems and practices . For example, one employer defined data-driven targets for the representation and advancement of diverse talent across dimensions (beyond gender and ethnicity) and role types (executive, management, technical, board)—leveraging powerful analytics to track progress and foster transparency along the way.

Do we enable individual growth?

Evidence suggests that individual growth, learning, and development programs are effective 47 Arnold B. Bakker and Evangelia Demerouti, “Towards a model of work engagement,” Career Development International , 2008, Volume 13, Issue 3. ways to combat burnout and to retain and engage employees, and therefore are important for addressing growing talent and skills shortages within organizations. Employers who “double down” on talent redeployment, mobility, reskilling, and upskilling tend to see improvement across a range of financial, organizational, and employee experience metrics. In a recent study of extensive employee data, offering lateral career opportunities was two-and-half times more predictive of employee retention than compensation, and 12 times more predictive than promotions 48 “Why every leader,” 2022. —signaling an opportunity for leaders to support employee desires to learn, explore, and grow way beyond traditional career progression.

Investing in your employees’ capabilities can drive financial returns, is often cheaper than hiring, and signals to employees that they are valued and have an important role in the organization.

Do we promote sustainable work?

Promoting sustainable work goes beyond managing workload. It’s about enabling employees to have a sense of control and predictability, flexibility, and sufficient time for daily recovery. It’s also about leading with compassion and empathy 49 “It’s time to eliminate bad bosses. They are harmful and expensive,” Potential Project, The Human Leader, April 2022. —tailoring interventions based on where, when, and how work can be done , and how different groups are more likely to (re)establish socio-emotional ties  after a long period of isolation and loss of social cohesion .

One technology company is using real-time data on employee preferences to rapidly test and iterate solutions that work for specific groups around return-to-office options. To find solutions that work for your employees, consider adopting a test-and-learn  mindset. This approach can help the organization make progress while adapting as context evolves (a hallmark of more productive  organizations).

Are we holding leaders accountable?

Many organizations consider people leadership criteria in their performance management. Yet, there is substantial room to grow when it comes to employers providing transparency around employee mental-health and well-being objectives and metrics. 50 Workplace Mental Health Blogs , One Mind, “Fix performance management by aligning it with employee mental health,” blog entry by Daryl Tol, March 2, 2022; Garett Slettebak, “Measuring progress on workplace mental health”, One Mind at Work, March 24, 2022.

Organizations that are doing this well have set clear expectations for managers to lead in a way that is supportive of employee mental health and well-being. 51 Taylor Adams et al., Mind the workplace: Work health survey 2021 , Mental Health America, 2021. They offer training to help managers identify, proactively ask about, and listen to employees’ mental-health and well-being needs. They also introduce mental-health “pulse” checks and incorporate relevant questions into the broader employee satisfaction surveys, to establish a baseline and track trends in how employees are feeling. Discussion on employee mental health and well-being can be incorporated into regular leadership meetings, including concerns, risks, and potential actions.

To encourage leaders to lead by example and increase their accountability, some employers embed employee mental-health support into leaders’ reviews based on anonymous upward feedback from their teams. Finally, some companies are exploring if they can go even further and tie incentives to short- and long-term employee mental-health and well-being objectives.

Are we effectively tackling stigma?

As noted in a previous McKinsey article , the majority of employers and employees acknowledge the presence of stigma 52 In the context of employee mental health, stigma is defined as a level of shame, prejudice, or discrimination toward people with mental-health or substance-use conditions. in their workplaces. Stigma has been shown to have real costs to workforce productivity, often exacerbating underlying conditions because of people being afraid to seek help for mental-health needs and driving down an employee’s self-worth and engagement.

We see several actions that organizations are taking to eliminate stigma. 53 Erica Coe, Jenny Cordina, Kana Enomoto, and Nikhil Seshan, “ Overcoming stigma: Three strategies toward better mental health in the workplace ,” July 23, 2021. Leading by example can make a difference, with senior leaders stepping forward to describe personal struggles with mental health, using nonstigmatizing language. 54 Evelien Brouwers et al., “To disclose or not to disclose: A multi-stakeholder focus group study on mental health issues in the work environment. Journal of Occupational Rehabilitation , 2020, Volume 30, Number 1. Leaders showing vulnerability helps to remove shame and promote a psychologically safe culture. 55 Global thriving at work framework , MindForward Alliance, 2020.

Stigma can also be reduced by companies prioritizing mental wellness as critical for peak performance instead of rewarding overwork at the expense of rest and renewal—rewarding an “athlete” mindset instead of overemphasizing a “hero.” This can begin to shift perception of signs of burnout or other mental-health needs as being indicative of a moral failing. Finally, creating a dedicated role to support employee mental health and well-being and appointing a senior leader, such as chief wellness officer, will increase awareness and show commitment.

Do our resources serve employee needs?

Leaders should evaluate whether mental-health and well-being resources are at parity with physical-health benefits and how frequently they are being used by employees. An increasing number of employers have expanded access to mental-health services 56 Charles Ingoglia, “Now more than ever, employers must provide mental health support for employees,” National Council for Mental Wellbeing, May 4, 2022. ; however, research  shows that almost 70 percent of employees find it challenging to access those services.

In a previous survey , 45 percent of respondents who had left their jobs cited the need to take care of family as an influential factor in their decision (with a similar proportion of respondents who are considering quitting also citing the demands of family care). Expanding childcare, nursing services, or other home- and family-focused benefits could help keep such employees from leaving and show that you value them. Patagonia, long the standard-bearer for progressive workplace policies, retains nearly 100 percent of its new mothers with on-site childcare and other benefits for parents.

Never in history have organizations around the world devoted so much attention and capital to improving employee mental health and well-being. It is lamentable that these investments are not always providing a good return regarding improved outcomes. Employers that take the time to understand the problem at hand—and pursue a preventative, systemic approach focused on causes instead of symptoms—should see material improvements in outcomes and succeed in attracting and retaining valuable talent. More broadly, employers globally have an opportunity to play a pivotal role in helping people achieve material improvements in health. With collaboration and shared commitment, employers can make a meaningful difference in the lives of their employees and the communities they live in.

The McKinsey Health Institute (MHI) is collaborating with leading organizations around the world to achieve material improvements in health—adding years to life and life to years. As part of that, MHI is focused on improving employee mental health and well-being at scale—in a way that is good for business, for employees, and for the communities they live in.

To stay updated about MHI’s initiative on employee mental health and well-being, sign up at McKinsey.com/mhi/contact-us .

Jacqueline Brassey is a director of research science in McKinsey’s Luxemburg office, Erica Coe is a partner in the Atlanta office, Martin Dewhurst is a senior partner in the London office, Kana Enomoto is a senior expert in the Washington, DC, office, and Barbara Jeffery is a partner in the London office; they are all leaders with McKinsey Health Institute (MHI). Renata Giarola , in the Southern California office, and Brad Herbig , in the Philadelphia office, are consultants with MHI.

The authors wish to thank Yueyang Chen, Elena Chit, Aaron de Smet, Soheil Eshghi, Lars Hartenstein, Tom Latkovic, David Mendelsohn, Roxy Merkand, Isidora Mitic, Bill Schaninger, Wilmar Schaufeli, Jeris Stueland, Berend Terluin, Karen van Dam, and Marieke van Hoffen for their contributions to this article.

This article was edited by Allan Gold, a senior editorial advisor in Washington, DC, and Elizabeth Newman, an executive editor in the Chicago office.

Explore a career with us

Related articles.

Image showing people from various ages gathered around as part of a community to illustrate how six years of higher quality life for everyone is within reach in the report titled “Adding years to life and life to years"

Adding years to life and life to years

National surveys reveal disconnect between employees and employers around mental health

National surveys reveal disconnect between employees and employers around mental health need

Businesswoman looking fatigued

The state of burnout for women in the workplace

IMAGES

  1. Examples of economic problems

    economics problem solving example

  2. PPT

    economics problem solving example

  3. Table Problem: Solving for Total Product, Marginal Product, and Average Product

    economics problem solving example

  4. 1 The basic economic problem

    economics problem solving example

  5. PPT

    economics problem solving example

  6. Solving Basic Economic Problems

    economics problem solving example

VIDEO

  1. 06 Problem Solving Equivalent Fractions 2

  2. 10 Problems of Brexit: Why The Economic COSTS Keep Growing

  3. problem solving

  4. Economic Problem l Causes of Economic Problem (English Medium)

  5. What are our biggest economic challenges?

  6. Problem Solving Lesson #5

COMMENTS

  1. Examples of economic problems

    Examples of economic problems. The fundamental economic problem is the issue of scarcity but unlimited wants. Scarcity implies there is only a limited quantity of resources, e.g. finite fossil fuels. Because of scarcity, there is a constant opportunity cost - if you use resources to consume one good, you cannot consume another.

  2. Assignments

    Problem Set 3 (PDF) Problem Set 4 (PDF) Problem Set 5 (PDF) Problem Set 6 Solutions (PDF) Problem Set 8 (PDF) Problem Set 9 Solutions (PDF) Problem Set 10 (PDF) Problem Set 10 Solutions (PDF) This section contains the problem sets and solutions for the course.

  3. Problem Set 1

    The problem set is comprised of challenging questions that test your understanding of the material covered in the course. Make sure you have mastered the concepts and problem solving techniques from the following sessions before attempting the problem set: Introduction to Microeconomics. Applying Supply and Demand.

  4. 1.3 How Economists Use Theories and Models to Understand Economic

    John Maynard Keynes (1883-1946), one of the greatest economists of the twentieth century, pointed out that economics is not just a subject area but also a way of thinking. Keynes famously wrote in the introduction to a fellow economist's book: "[Economics] is a method rather than a doctrine, an apparatus of the mind, a technique of thinking, which helps its possessor to draw correct ...

  5. Example question calculating CPI and inflation

    Example question calculating CPI and inflation. The Consumer Price Index (CPI) is a measure of the average change in prices of a typical basket of goods and services over time. It is used to gauge inflation and changes in the cost of living. The CPI might overstate changes in the cost of living because it doesn't always account for how people ...

  6. What is the fundamental economic problem?

    Resource Scarcity. Opportunity cost. The basic economic problem, also known as the fundamental economic problem, refers to the scarcity of resources in relation to the unlimited wants and needs of individuals and societies. It is the central issue in economics and arises due to the imbalance between what people desire and the resources ...

  7. Problem Set 7

    Problem Solving Video. In the video below, a teaching assistant demonstrates his approach to the solution for problem 2a-e from the problem set. The teaching assistant notes common mistakes made by students and provides problem solving techniques for approaching similar questions on the problem set and exams. View video page. Download video.

  8. Economic Models and Problems

    Economic relationships can often be expressed as mathematical functions. Variable Y is a function of variable X; when X changes, Y responds either by increasing or decreasing. Mathematically, economic relationships can be captured by linear or non-linear functions. (4) Y = F (X) Linear Functions: Y = 20 + 4X. D = 100 âˆ' 2P.

  9. Lesson Explainer: Fundamental Economic Problem

    Example 1: The Fundamental Economic Problem. Which of the following are the two root causes of the fundamental economic problem? Scarcity of resources; ... In other words, economics seeks to solve the fundamental economic problem. Depending on the types of economic problems considered, economics can be divided into several branches. ...

  10. Problem Solving in Economics

    Throughout, the emphasis is on how these techniques are fruitfully deployed in constructing economic models and solving economic problems. It bridges the gap between mathematical analysis and economic logic. For readers, it builds confidence in constructing their own models for purposes of analysis. The book is well-suited for self-study.

  11. Problem Set: Math in Economics

    Problem Set: Math in Economics. Test your understanding of the learning outcomes in this module by working through the following problems. These problems aren't graded, but they give you a chance to practice before taking the quiz. If you'd like to try a problem again, you can click the link that reads, "Try another version of this ...

  12. PDF Mathematical Economics Practice Problems and Solutions

    Solution 1c. SOC: d2Π/dQ2 = -2b < 0, since it is given that b > 0. Thus, Q = (a-c)/2b is a maximum. Problem 2. Suppose the firm faces a demand curve for its product P = 32 - 2Q, and the firm's costs of production and marketing are C(Q) = 2Q2. Find the following. The formula for profit Π in terms of Q.

  13. 1.1 What Is Economics, and Why Is It Important?

    As you can see, economics affects far more than business. For example: Virtually every major problem facing the world today, from global warming, to world poverty, to the conflicts in Syria, Afghanistan, and Somalia, has an economic dimension. If you are going to be part of solving those problems, you need to be able to understand them.

  14. The power of economics to explain and shape the world

    In 14.009 (Economics and Society's Greatest Problems), a first-year class taught by Nobel laureates, MIT students discover the power of economics to help solve major societal problems.

  15. 35 Examples of Economic Issues

    The most popular articles on Simplicable in the past day. 7 Examples of Commodities. The definition of commodity with examples. 9 Examples of an Economic Bad. Common examples of an economic bad. 6 Examples of a Run Rate. The definition of run rate with calculation examples. 6 Examples of a Common Good.

  16. Basic Economic Problem

    The fundamental economic problem is the issue of scarcity and how best to produce and distribute these scare resources. Scarcity means there is a finite supply of goods and raw materials. Finite resources mean they are limited and can run out. Unlimited wants mean that there is no end to the quantity of goods and services people would like to ...

  17. Lesson summary: Introduction to Macroeconomics

    When thinking about economic problems, we can use either positive analysis or normative analysis. Positive analysis is objective, fact-based, and cause-and-effect thinking about problems. When economists disagree it is typically due to different normative analysis. ... Fashion is a great example, I watch as scarcity drives the price up ...

  18. Boost Your Economics Problem-Solving Skills Today

    For example, behavioral economics combines psychology with economic theory to explain why people might not always act rationally. Embrace a broad perspective to enrich your problem-solving ...

  19. 1.2: What Is Economics, and Why Is It Important?

    As you can see, economics affects far more than business. For example: Virtually every major problem facing the world today, from global warming, to world poverty, to the conflicts in Syria, Afghanistan, and Somalia, has an economic dimension. If you are going to be part of solving those problems, you need to be able to understand them.

  20. PDF for Economics Lecturers Problem-based Learning

    The design of PBL tasks for economics students, along with examples, is discussed in section 3. The Handbook for Economics Lecturers 4 Figure 1 Problem-based learning and skill development Figure 2 The PBL process Transferable skills Time management, teamwork, independent learning, decision taking, problem solving, communicating ideas and ...

  21. PDF for Economics Lecturers Case Studies

    The process may involve, for example, the production of a unique communication (presentation) or a plan of operations (research proposal). Case studies foster this skill by requiring students to identify relevant information, summarise fundamental concepts and present a concise summary of main events. Evaluation.

  22. Chapter Three

    Caltrans identifies additional, more specific benefits in its guidance Project Development Procedures Manual (PDPM Chapter 19, p. 19â 7; Value Analysis Team Guide 2003, p. 1.3): â ¢ To foster a team approach to problem-solving and proj- ect development; â ¢ To help build consensus among stakeholders; â ¢ To identify and develop ...

  23. 7 Problem-Solving Skills That Can Help You Be a More ...

    Although problem-solving is a skill in its own right, a subset of seven skills can help make the process of problem-solving easier. These include analysis, communication, emotional intelligence, resilience, creativity, adaptability, and teamwork. 1. Analysis. As a manager, you'll solve each problem by assessing the situation first.

  24. Solving US construction's worker shortage

    Between December 2019 and 2021, construction wages grew by 7.9 percent. 2Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages, US Bureau of Labor Statistics. Competition from other sectors for the same pool of labor is heating up, too. For example, over the same period, transportation and warehousing wages grew by 12.6 percent.

  25. Hotel staffing shortages

    AHLA points out that similar staff shortages extend to hotels across the United States as employment in the hotel industry decreased by almost 400,000 jobs between February 2020 and August 2022, with more than 115,000 job openings yet unfilled. 2"87% of surveyed hotels report staffing shortages," American Hotel & Lodging Association ...

  26. Solve

    Integration. ∫ 01 xe−x2dx. Limits. x→−3lim x2 + 2x − 3x2 − 9. Online math solver with free step by step solutions to algebra, calculus, and other math problems. Get help on the web or with our math app.

  27. Addressing employee burnout: Are you solving the right problem?

    According to the World Health Organization, burnout is an occupational phenomenon. It is driven by a chronic imbalance between job demands 1 Job demands are physical, social, or organizational aspects of the job that require sustained physical or mental effort and are therefore associated with certain physiological and psychological costs—for example, work overload and expectations ...