• Search Menu
  • Sign in through your institution
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • Why Submit?
  • About International Studies Review
  • About the International Studies Association
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Issue Cover

Article Contents

Introduction, theoretical predictions, what the empirical evidence says, empirical challenges, acknowledgments.

  • < Previous

On the Impact of Inequality on Growth, Human Development, and Governance

ORCID logo

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

Ines A Ferreira, Rachel M Gisselquist, Finn Tarp, On the Impact of Inequality on Growth, Human Development, and Governance, International Studies Review , Volume 24, Issue 1, March 2022, viab058, https://doi.org/10.1093/isr/viab058

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

Inequality is a major international development challenge. This is so from an ethical perspective and because greater inequality is perceived to be detrimental to key socioeconomic and political outcomes. Still, informed debate requires clear evidence. This article contributes by taking stock and providing an up-to-date overview of the current knowledge on the impact of income inequality, specifically on three important outcomes: (1) economic growth; (2) human development, with a focus on health and education as two of its dimensions; and (3) governance, with emphasis on democracy. With particular attention to work in economics, which is especially developed on these topics, this article reveals that the existing evidence is somewhat mixed and argues for further in-depth empirical work across disciplines. It also points to explanations for the lack of consensus embedded in data quality and availability, measurement issues, and shortcomings of the different methods employed. Finally, we suggest promising future research avenues relying on experimental work for microlevel analysis and reiterate the need for more region- and country-specific studies and improvements in the availability and reliability of data.

La desigualdad es un desafío importante para el desarrollo internacional. Esto es así desde una perspectiva ética y debido a que la mayor desigualdad se percibe como perjudicial para los resultados políticos y socioeconómicos clave. Aun así, los debates informados requieren pruebas claras. Esta revisión contribuye estudiando la situación y ofreciendo un resumen actualizado del conocimiento actual sobre el impacto de la desigualdad de ingresos, específicamente en tres resultados importantes: (1) el crecimiento económico; (2) el desarrollo humano, con un enfoque en la salud y la educación como dos de sus dimensiones; y (3) la gobernanza, con énfasis en la democracia. Prestando especial atención al trabajo en economía que se desarrolla particularmente sobre estos temas, este ensayo demuestra que las pruebas existentes están mezcladas de alguna manera y argumenta a favor de promover el trabajo empírico en profundidad en todas las disciplinas. También señala las explicaciones para la falta de consenso que están integradas en la calidad y la disponibilidad de los datos, los problemas de medición y los defectos de los diferentes métodos empleados. Finalmente, sugerimos prometedoras vías de investigación para el futuro que dependen del trabajo experimental para el análisis a pequeña escala, y reiteramos la necesidad de realizar más estudios específicos de la región y el país, así como mejoras en la disponibilidad y la confiabilidad de los datos.

L'inégalité est un défi majeur du développement international. Il en est ainsi d'un point de vue éthique et parce qu'une plus grande inégalité est perçue comme allant au détriment des principaux résultats socio-économiques et politiques. Toutefois, des preuves claires sont nécessaires pour débattre en connaissance de cause. Cette analyse y contribue en faisant le bilan et en offrant une présentation à jour des connaissances actuelles sur l'impact de l'inégalité des revenus, en particulier sur trois résultats importants: (1) la croissance économique, (2) le développement humain, en se concentrant sur la santé et l’éducation en tant que deux de ses dimensions, et (3) la gouvernance, en mettant l'accent sur la démocratie. Cet essai accorde une attention particulière aux travaux en économie qui sont particulièrement développés sur ces sujets et révèle que les preuves existantes sont quelque peu mitigées et plaide pour un travail empirique plus approfondi dans toutes les disciplines. Il met également en évidence des explications du manque de consensus inhérent à la qualité et à la disponibilité des données, aux problèmes de mesure et aux lacunes des différentes méthodes employées. Enfin, nous suggérons des pistes de recherches futures prometteuses qui s'appuieraient sur des travaux expérimentaux pour l'analyse au niveau micro et nous réitérons la nécessité de réaliser davantage d’études spécifiques aux régions et aux pays et d'améliorer la disponibilité et la fiabilité des données.

Recent decades have witnessed sharp rises in inequality of income and wealth in many countries (though neither globally nor everywhere) as well as in the observed level of inequality of opportunities in access to basic services, such as health and education. Concern with these trends is paramount in Goal 10 of the Sustainable Development Goals approved by the United Nations General Assembly in 2015, aiming at “reducing inequality within and among countries.” The COVID-19 pandemic, which has both reflected and exacerbated inequalities, further spotlights this objective.

Pursuing this goal can obviously be justified from an ethical perspective. The case is also made in instrumental terms, with reference to potential negative effects of inequality on a variety of socioeconomic and political outcomes. The World Development Report (2006) drew attention to the implications of high levels of inequality for long-term development ( World Bank 2006 ). Indeed, economists in particular have long been concerned with the relationship between equity and efficiency 1 ; interestingly, the old classical view, contrary to the 2006 report, suggests a contradiction between equality and development.

Informed policy debate requires clear evidence on these impacts. This analytical essay provides a “state-of-art” on research on this big question. While recent reviews of the literature tend to focus on the impact of inequality on one specific outcome, we have a broader scope; we aim to bring new clarity to the debate by taking stock of the current knowledge on the effects on three important outcomes: (1) economic growth; (2) human development, with a focus on health and education as two of its dimensions; and (3) governance, with emphasis on democracy. While we start by highlighting how the various processes are connected, we address the impacts of inequality on these outcomes separately, developing an overview of the core arguments and underlying mechanisms, and of the existing evidence, with a particular focus on cross-country insights.

We draw in particular on the large and well-developed literature on these topics in economics while also taking key insights from other disciplines. 2 Our focus is on broad outcomes that are of particular importance for international development and that received great attention in studies examining the impact of inequality across disciplines. The effects of inequality on economic growth have been extensively debated in economics, the main disciplinary focus of this article. However, health and education—two important channels with high policy relevance—have also been the object of investigation in public health studies. Moreover, the field of political science has greatly contributed to the debate addressing the effects of inequality on political aspects, including those related to democratic governance. 3

Building on previous reviews focusing on specific outcomes (e.g., Voitchovsky 2011 ; Neves and Silva 2014 ; O'Donnell, van Doorslaer, and van Ourti 2015 ; Scheve and Stasavage 2017 ), but adopting the broader outlook of the seminal review by Thorbecke and Charumilind (2002) , this article provides an updated and comprehensive perspective on the consequences of inequality in three core areas of concern for international studies. 4

We combine the main theoretical arguments on the impact of inequality and underlying transmission channels in a general framework, providing a simplified view while emphasizing the connections between different processes. Overall, our review of an extensive body of work suggests there is no clear consensus emerging from the empirical evidence, and we argue there is room for additional in-depth work to uncover the effects through specific mechanisms of transmission. In particular, there is no consensus from the results of studies using reduced-form equations to examine the effect on growth, and less work has been dedicated to exploring the channels of transmission. Moreover, the negative link between inequality and secondary school enrolment is confirmed by the evidence, but further research is needed in terms of other education outcomes. The economic and public health literatures disagree on whether the negative effect of inequality on health is confirmed by the existing evidence, and there are mixed results emerging from political scientists for the effects of inequality on democracy and political participation. We advance the underlying explanations for this state of affairs, related to the challenges inherent in data quality and availability, measurement issues, and shortcomings of the different estimation methods employed, and suggest avenues for further research.

In the second section, we offer an outline of the main theoretical predictions of the effects of inequality on socioeconomic outcomes and on governance, presenting different channels of transmission. The third section follows the same structure and reviews the existing empirical evidence. We reflect on key empirical challenges of estimating the effects of inequality in the fourth section. The fifth section concludes.

Several theoretical explanations exist across disciplines for the effects of inequality on socioeconomic and political outcomes. Before we describe in more detail these channels of influence and the resulting outcomes, we highlight a broader set of arguments, which act as a roadmap for the rest of the section.  Figure 1 provides a schematic overview.

Diagram with main outcomes of inequality

Diagram with main outcomes of inequality

Source : Authors’ elaboration.

Starting from the left- to the right-hand side, the diagram represents different channels of transmission of the effects of higher levels of inequality, their intermediate effects, and the resulting positive or negative impact on our three outcomes of interest: growth, 5 human development, and democracy. We broadly divide these channels according to their underlying drivers: the poor, the population at large or the average, and the wealthy.

Overall, the diagram suggests that high inequality has predominantly harmful effects on our three outcomes of interest, according to theoretical explanations advanced in the literature. The dominant view then runs contra the expectations of the classical theorists, i.e., that inequality has a positive impact on growth, via savings and investment (shown at the top of  figure 1 ). We highlight six main transmission channels.

First, inequality affects incentives for savings and investment and the overall level of institutional quality through its influence on policy making and increased political instability, and consequent effects on property rights and the regulatory framework. This has implications for growth both directly and indirectly via governance.

Second, by favoring private over public investment, inequality affects investment in public goods, namely health and education, with implications across the three outcomes. Third, and related, inequality results in underinvestment on human capital resulting from credit constraints, and high fertility, which affects education levels and overall economic growth.

Fourth, high taxation will be demanded by a well-endowed median voter and the likelihood of transition to and stability of democracy will also depend on the pressure for redistribution, which is higher with lower levels of equality. Moreover, and fifth, a small middle class will affect the demand not only for democracy but also for manufactures.

Finally, high levels of polarization will lead to weak social cohesion via their effects on social capital, as well as low trust and potential high levels in violent crime, which affect health directly and indirectly via investment in public health. Additionally, the concentration of power on the rich leads to increased probability of political violence and affects political engagement.

Some of these channels affect all of the outcomes. For instance, the effect through investment in public goods has detrimental effects on human development, and on growth and democracy. Moreover, the resulting polarization and social discontent, which increase the chances of political violence, again negatively impact the three outcomes. However, there is also some indication that, when it comes to growth, the effect might be ambiguous depending on the predominance of the effects of transmission mechanisms. The channel through savings (and investment) points to a potential positive effect, while the different effects through public investment, taxation, the structure of demand, imperfect credit markets, fertility, and social discontent suggest potential negative consequences for growth.

This section uncovers more details about these different theoretical predictions. It starts by introducing the main hypotheses advanced for the effects of inequality on growth. While the approach in this article considers the three outcomes separately, we recognize that they are not disjointed or orthogonal and refer to the links between them. Nevertheless, a full discussion of these interlinkages is beyond the scope of this article. As suggested in  figure 1 and described in more detail below, some of these channels point to the impact of inequality on our remaining outcomes of interest, namely education and health, or governance. We return to them in the remaining two subsections, where we expand to consider the insights from other strands of literature.

How Inequality Affects Growth

An extensive literature examines the effects of inequality on growth, 6 highlighting multiple channels of transmission. 7 The early studies, referred to as the classical approach, argued that there is a positive effect of inequality on growth, explained via savings or incentives. However, subsequent work questioned this view, challenging some of its assumptions and proposing different channels of influence. Most of this work has predicted a negative effect of inequality. We briefly outline these channels in the next paragraphs and refer to Bourguignon (2015) , Neves and Silva (2014) , and Voitchovsky (2011) for complementary detail and reviews. 8

High inequality is growth enhancing

We start by drawing attention to the view of classical economists on income inequality, according to which there was a contradiction between equality and development (for a discussion of the trade-off between efficiency and equity, see Thorbecke 2016 ). Adam Smith defended that inequality had benefits based on arguments of (1) “trickle-down effects”—the increase in wealth will eventually benefit the poor, (2) incentive effects—inequality is necessary to encourage competition and to provide incentives for innovation, and (3) social stability—the different ranks in wealth distribution ensure peace and stability in society ( Walraevens 2021 , 3–6). The famous Kuznets curve ( Kuznets 1955 ), shaped like an inverted U-relationship between growth and inequality (as per capita income increases), seemed to reinforce this view. 9

Developed in the 1950s and 1960s, the so-called classical approach followed a similar line of thinking, based on arguments related to savings and incentives. The prominent work by Kaldor (1956) suggests a positive link between inequality and growth via saving rates, based on the assumption that the higher the level of income, the higher is the marginal propensity to save ( Aghion, Caroli, and García-Peñalosa 1999 , 1620). At the core of this assumption that the rich have a higher marginal propensity to save relative to the poor are two hypotheses: (1) consumption smoothing cannot occur unless the subsistence level of consumption is achieved, and therefore the poor cannot save, and (2) the possibility to save is conditioned by the previous generations, which leads to a concentration of savings in rich households ( Thorbecke and Charumilind 2002 , 1483).

Under this assumption, the redistribution of resources toward the rich leads to higher savings, which, in turn, improves growth via investment. This link is particularly important if one considers limited borrowing possibilities, initial setup costs, and the large investments involved in risky and high-return opportunities ( Aghion, Caroli, and García-Peñalosa 1999 , 1620; Voitchovsky 2011 , 558). Big investment projects involve large sunk costs, and therefore investment relies on the concentration of wealth in individuals to be able to afford them.

A second argument drew on the role of incentives and on the trade-off between efficiency and social justice mentioned earlier ( Aghion, Caroli, and García-Peñalosa 1999 , 1620). At the microlevel, in a simple moral hazard model, if output depends on unobserved effort, then setting a constant reward (in the form of wage) discourages effort, whereas linking the reward to output can be inefficient due to agents’ risk aversion. The same argument maintains at the aggregate level, assuming identical agents and/or perfect capital markets. As explained by Aghion, Caroli, and García-Peñalosa (1999 , 1620), redistribution will have a direct negative effect on growth as well as a negative indirect effect through the reduction in the incentives to accumulate wealth (resulting from redistribution through income tax).

High inequality has a negative effect on growth

Credit market imperfections and fertility.

The effects of inequality on growth via credit market imperfections and via fertility are linked by their focus on the circumstances of the poor and on human capital investment ( Voitchovsky 2011 ). The first channel addresses the impact of credit imperfections on investment decisions. If one considers the high fixed costs associated with, for instance, education, limitations on the access to credit may lead to underinvestment in human capital, which implies a negative impact on growth ( Neves and Silva 2014 , 3). This was the argument resulting from the Galor and Zeira (1993) model. Assuming that credit markets are imperfect and that investment in human capital is indivisible, they conclude that the distribution of wealth has an impact on aggregate investment in human capital and therefore on growth, both in the short and in the long run.

The reasoning behind the link between inequality and growth through fertility was similar. Poor families might not have the resources to invest in their children's education and, thus, their income depends on having bigger families; for richer families, it might be optimal to invest more in education and, consequently, to have fewer children ( Gründler and Scheuermeyer 2018 , 295). In this line of thinking, de la Croix and Doepke (2003) argued that a high fertility differential between the rich and the poor lowered average education. Thus, inequality leads to lower levels of human capital accumulation via the increased fertility differential and, therefore, to lower growth.

Taxation and regulatory policies

Seminal work by Alesina and Rodrik (1994) as well as Persson and Tabellini (1994) pointed to a negative link between inequality and growth through government expenditure and taxation, combining endogenous growth theory with political economy insights. They proposed two different mechanisms that Perotti (1996 , 151) termed “political” and “economic,” respectively. The Alesina and Rodrik (1994) model drew on the median voter theorem and considered tax revenues equally distributed among all individuals. Given that the tax rate is proportional to income, individuals with a lower share of capital income (relative to labor income) prefer higher taxes. Thus, the more equitable the distribution in the economy, the better endowed is the median voter, and the lower the equilibrium level of taxation. A lower rate of tax corresponds to a higher growth rate, which led them to conclude that there is an inverse relationship between inequality and subsequent economic growth.

Persson and Tabellini (1994) reached the same conclusion considering the role of incentives for productive accumulation and for growth. According to them, the incentives necessary for private savings and investment rely on individuals’ ability to “appropriate privately the fruits of their efforts” ( Persson and Tabellini 1994 , 600), which are in turn influenced by tax and regulatory policies. Inequality gives rise to policies that do not protect property rights or allow full appropriation of returns to investment and is therefore associated with lower economic growth.

Still, this result was defied by Li and Zou (1998) . They offered a more general framework than that proposed by Alesina and Rodrik (1994) , considering that government spending could be directed not only to production services—which entered the production function—but also to consumption services—which entered the utility function. Adding this extension, they showed that a more equal distribution could lead to lower growth via higher taxation and that the effect of income inequality on growth is, therefore, ambiguous.

The view outlined in Alesina and Rodrik (1994) and in Persson and Tabellini (1994) was also challenged by an alternative perspective suggesting that redistributive policies might also have a positive effect on growth in the presence of imperfect credit and insurance markets and that the popular support for these policies decreases with inequality ( Bénabou 2000 ). When combined, these two mechanisms could lead to multiple steady states, while the correlation with growth depends on the balance between incentive distortions and credit constraints ( Neves and Silva 2014 , 4). Voitchovsky (2011 , 556) lists the criticism toward the median voter argument and highlights how the channel through redistribution does not gather consensus.

The structure of demand

Zweimüller (2000) described the role of redistribution on growth through innovation. Building on the assumption of hierarchical preferences, the distribution of income affects the structure of demand: poor people spend mainly on basic needs whereas rich people spend on luxury goods. According to the author, inequality affects growth through its effect on the time path faced by an innovator. When a new and expensive good is introduced in the market, only rich consumers can afford it, until the increasing demand drives the price–wage ratio down (due to economies of scale), opening up the market to mass consumers ( Voitchovsky 2011 , 557). The optimal consumption levels of those affected by redistribution dictate the overall effect of changes in income inequality on long-run growth ( Zweimüller 2000 ). An earlier study by Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1989) had already highlighted the importance of the middle class to the consumption of domestic manufactures and, therefore, to industrialization.

Sociopolitical instability and rent seeking

Another group of studies suggested a link between inequality and growth through sociopolitical instability, drawing attention to the effects on property rights. According to Alesina and Perotti (1996) , social unrest—resulting from social discontent caused by income inequality—can lead to an increasing probability of political violence as well as policy uncertainty and threats to property rights, which, in turn, have a negative impact on investment and thus on growth. Keefer and Knack (2002) claimed that income inequality leads to instability in government policies, namely those related to security of property rights, which affects the decisions of economic actors, and consequently slows the rate of growth. Relatedly, the Glaeser, Scheinkman, and Shleifer (2003) model showed a detrimental effect of inequality on property rights through the subversion of political regulatory and legal institutions by the rich for their own benefit.

The effect depends

Finally, we highlight contributions suggesting that different mechanisms might be present at different points. Galor and Moav (2004) proposed a unified theory between the credit market imperfections and the saving rate channels described earlier. According to them, the positive effect of inequality on growth suggested by classical theories corresponded to early stages of industrialization when physical capital accumulation is the primary driver of economic growth. However, at later stages, human capital accumulation becomes the main determinant of growth and credit constraints are largely binding, which explains the negative link between inequality and growth through credit market imperfections. As credit constraints become less binding due to wage increases, the aggregate effect of income distribution on growth is less significant.

A decade later, Halter, Oechslin, and Zweimüller (2014) presented a parsimonious theoretical model that takes into account both a short-term and a long-term effect of asset inequality. According to them, the short-term effect is positive and it occurs through an economic channel, whereas the long-term effect is negative and stems from a political economy channel.

How Inequality Affects Education and Health

Inequality can have both positive and negative effects on education.

While the literature examining the effects of education on inequality is extensive, the same is not true for studies looking at the other direction of causality. We distinguish between the arguments on the effects of inequality through expenditure on education and through school enrolment and attainment.

The provision of education depends on the willingness of citizens to redistribute resources via taxation, in line with Alesina and Rodrik (1994) and Perotti (1996 ). According to this political economy mechanism, increasing inequality will lead to lower availability of resources, as the rich will prefer not to contribute to public education, favoring private schools ( Mayer 2001 , 5). 10 Gutiérrez and Tanaka (2009) modeled the effect of inequality on school enrolment, and the preferred tax rate and expenditure per student focusing on parents’ decisions in developing countries. According to the authors, beyond a certain level of inequality, there is no longer support for public education. The model shows that, when considering the fact that parents can make a choice of sending their children either to work or to private or public schools, high inequality results in exiting public education, which has implications for the tax rate and expenditure per student. 11

According to the credit market imperfections’ channel discussed in section “How Inequality Affects Growth,” inequality creates obstacles in terms of access to education. In the presence of imperfect credit markets, the distribution of wealth affects the aggregate investment in human capital ( Galor and Zeira 1993 ; García-Peñalosa 1995 ). Additionally, inequality can affect enrolment by determining the number of poor who are able to substitute the return of child labor for school attendance ( Gutiérrez and Tanaka 2009 , 56). The Tanaka (2003) model shows that in contexts of high inequality, there is low support for public provision of schooling, which, in equilibrium, leads to a higher level of child labor.

The expected returns to the family from schooling will also affect the demand for education, as educated children are likely to have higher future income ( Birdsall 1999 , 17). If inequality is induced in part by increased returns to schooling, then there will be an incentive for children to stay in school and one could expect a positive relationship between an increase in inequality and educational attainment ( Mayer 2001 ; Thorbecke and Charumilind 2002 ; Dabla-Norris et al. 2015 ). 12

Inequality negatively affects health

The interest in understanding how income inequality affects health has instigated a broad range of work both in economics and in the fields of public health and sociology, 13 and different hypotheses are available. Generally, they suggest that inequality negatively affects health. Following O'Donnell, van Doorslaer, and van Ourti (2015) and Leigh, Jencks, and Smeeding (2011) , we distinguish between hypotheses that imply that the health of all individuals is affected and those that do not require that the health of every individual in society is under threat. 14

The first group of hypotheses proposes three different channels: public goods provision, social capital, and violent crime. 15 The effect through public goods provision can be negative or positive ( Leigh, Jencks, and Smeeding 2011 , 390). There will be a negative effect if inequality causes a reduction in the average value of publicly provided goods due to more heterogeneous preferences or if it enables the rich to acquire more political influence and, consequently, to pressure for a reduction in public spending on health. However, it can also be positive, given that as inequality increases among voters, the median voter will tend to support spending on health.

The effect through social capital builds on the assumption that income inequality leads to decreased social cohesion and, therefore, affects health through social 16 and psychosocial support, mechanisms of informal insurance, and diffusion of information ( O'Donnell, van Doorslaer, and van Ourti 2015 , 1501). Low trust can lead to disbelief about the improvements in health via public spending and links to higher mortality via smaller friendship networks as well ( Leigh, Jencks, and Smeeding 2011 , 390). Finally, although only a small percentage of deaths in developed countries results from violent crime, Leigh, Jencks, and Smeeding (2011 , 389) highlight the potentially larger secondary effects via increased stress about experiencing crime in the future. 17

In the second group of hypotheses, health depends on income at the individual level. The Wagstaff and van Doorslaer (2000) seminal review describes different interpretations. First, the absolute income hypothesis, which was also termed the “income artefact” hypothesis, suggests that the observed correlation between inequality and health is a result of the concave relationship between income and health; that is, the health gains of an additional unit of income are diminishing in an individual's income level. The term “artefact” applies to the fact that a redistribution of income leads to an increase in average population health even though there is no effect on the health of any individual, given their income. Second, the relative income hypothesis builds on the idea that psychosocial effects that result from individuals comparing their income with that of others (the mean income of the population or the community) affect health. Third, the deprivation hypothesis is a variation of the relative income hypothesis, and it argues that the crucial aspect is the extent of deprivation measured by the income gap. Fourth, and related, the relative position hypothesis states that what is important is the position of the individual in the income distribution.

How Inequality Affects Democratic Governance

In this section, we delve more deeply into the relationship between inequality and governance outcomes, democracy in particular, which have attracted considerable attention, especially within political economy and political science (see Bermeo 2009 ; Karl 2000 ). We start by focusing on the effects on democratic stability and democratic transition and then zoom in on the effects on political participation.

First, we refer back to the link between inequality and growth through political instability and social conflict described in section “High inequality has a negative effect on growth”. As highlighted by Fukuyama (2011 , 84), “[a] more likely reason why inequality is bad for growth is directly political: highly unequal countries are polarized between rich and poor, and the resulting social conflict destabilizes them, undermines democratic legitimacy, and reduces economic growth.” The summary in Thorbecke and Charumilind (2002 , 1486) suggests two main mechanisms: the relative deprivation hypothesis and resource mobilization. According to the first, discontent resulting from the gap between individual expected and achieved well-being leads to collective political violence. Inequality might deepen the grievances of certain groups or reduce the opportunity cost of engaging in violent conflict ( Dabla-Norris et al. 2015 , 9). Nevertheless, the second mechanism points to the ability of dissident groups to organize themselves as the key element.

The theoretical literature largely suggests negative effects of inequality on the likelihood of transition to and stability of democracy. It attributes an important role to democratic values and access to education, which are more likely to characterize citizens and the situation in equal societies, and to the middle class, which is more likely to promote tolerance and avoid extremist positions ( Houle 2015 , 145).

Two of the most prominent arguments for the link between inequality and democracy were presented in Boix (2003) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) . 18 The former argues that increasing levels of economic equality lead to a higher probability of democracy through redistribution. According to the theoretical predictions, the pressure for redistribution from the poor decreases with higher levels of equality, which means that a turn to democracy would be less costly for the holders of the most productive assets; that is, the payment of tax is less costly than repression.

The Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) predictions indicate a nonlinear, inverted U-shaped relationship. On the one hand, greater intergroup inequality increases the appeal of a revolution for citizens to increase their share in the income of the economy, thus increasing the likelihood of democracy. On the other hand, higher inequality also means higher aversion to democracy by elites as their tax burden is greater, thus discouraging democratization. Accordingly, the authors suggested that, for high levels of equality, there is no incentive for citizens to challenge the system and the interests of the elites are preserved. In societies with high levels of inequality, citizens try to rise up against the system, but this meets great repression from the elite, leading to a repressive non-democracy or a revolution, in certain cases. Therefore, the likelihood of democracy is higher for middle levels of inequality.

However, Houle (2009) highlighted three problems with these theories. First, they do not apply to transitions that are driven from above (e.g., from intra-elite competition). Second, the net effect of inequality is ambiguous because it makes redistribution more costly for the elites but, at the same time, it increases the population's demand for regime change. Finally, they ignore collective action problems and the challenges of mobilizing the population. More recently, Ansell and Samuels (2010) departed from Boix (2003) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) and proposed a contractarian approach that placed the focus on the citizens’ demand for protection against expropriation. According to these authors, democracy emerges from land equality and income inequality.

We briefly refer to a related group of studies examining the link from inequality to institutional quality and refer to Chong and Gradstein (2019) for details. Chong and Gradstein (2007 , 2019 ) argue that there is double causality: while inequality leads to subversion of institutions through the political power of the elite, poor institutional quality also causes a higher level of inequality. Furthermore, Kotschy and Sunde (2017) have proposed that inequality interacts with political institutions in shaping institutional quality. Some have also suggested that a link exists between inequality and corruption, via self-reinforcing mechanisms and social norms (e.g., Jong-sung and Khagram 2005 ) as well as via low trust (e.g., Rothstein and Uslaner 2005 ). 19

Finally, a strand of studies in political science has argued that there is a link between inequality and political participation. As reviewed in Solt (2008) , the theoretical predictions lead to different possible outcomes of economic inequality on political engagement 20 : a negative effect, a positive effect, or an effect that depends on the level of income of the individual. The first outcome is a result of the concentration of power: societies that are more unequal have a higher concentration of power, which has implications for how the issues that separate the rich from the poor are addressed in the political sphere. The rich will have a lower need to engage in the political process whereas the poor will feel removed from politics. The prediction of a positive effect results from the fact that the divergence in the views of the rich and the poor will be more apparent in societies with higher inequality, which should lead to higher participation in the political process. Finally, the last prediction hinges on the fact that political engagement entails the use of resources. Thus, with higher levels of inequality, one should expect greater engagement from the rich, who have more resources available, and lower political engagement from the poor. 21

We now move on to discuss the main insights from empirical analyses following the structure of the previous section. Although we focus here on cross-country analysis, which makes up a significant part of the evidence base, we also refer to studies examining these links at the regional level, especially in the United States.

Direct link

where |$g$| is the average annual growth rate, frequently measured as the log difference of gross domestic product (GDP) per capita; INEQ is a measure of income inequality (usually the Gini coefficient); Z m is a set of other variables commonly used in standard growth regressions; and u is the usual error term. This was then estimated, typically using basic ordinary least squares. To avoid reverse causation, inequality was measured at the beginning of the time span for growth, which usually considers a period of twenty to thirty years, and in some cases, authors employed instrumental variables to address endogeneity concerns.

Summary of results from selected empirical work testing the link between inequality and growth

General findingReferenceData (no. countries; period)Measure of inequalityData sourceData structure; estimation method(s)
Negative effect = 46/70; 1960–1985Gini for land and income ; Cross-section; OLS, 2SLS
= 56; 1960–1985Pre-tax income share accruing to the third quintile (note: measure of equality) Cross-section; OLS, 2SLS
= 74/81; 1970–1978Coefficient of variation; Theil's index; Gini; share of income of the poorest 40% to the share of income of the richest 20%United Nations Indicator of Social Development; ; Cross-section; OLS, WLS, 2SLS
) = 67; 1960–1985Combined share of the third and fourth quintiles ; Cross-section; OLS, 2SLS
= 31; 1970–2010Gini; bottom inequality; top inequalityOECD income distribution datasetPanel; Sys-GMM
= 153; 1960–2009GiniSWIIDPanel; Sys-GMM
= 164; 1965–2014GiniSWIIDPanel; two-step Sys-GMM
Positive effect = 46; 1960–1990GiniDSPanel; FE, RE
= 45; 1966–1995GiniDSPanel; FE, RE, Diff-GMM
= 123; 1960–2010GiniSWIIDPanel; LSDV
It depends
 Controls = 87/66; 1960–1992Gini; land distributionDSCross-section; OLS
 Level of income = 84; 1965–1995Gini; quintile sharesDSPanel; 3SLS
= 102/23; 1960–2000Gini; percentile ratiosWIID; LISPanel; Sys-GMM
 Non-linear effects = 45; 1965–1995GiniDSPanel; RE, GMM, Kernel regression
 Profile of inequality = 21; 1975–2000Gini; top-end and bottom-end inequalityLISPanel; Sys-GMM
 Time = 106; 1965–2005GiniDS; WIIDPanel; Diff-GMM, Sys-GMM
General findingReferenceData (no. countries; period)Measure of inequalityData sourceData structure; estimation method(s)
Negative effect = 46/70; 1960–1985Gini for land and income ; Cross-section; OLS, 2SLS
= 56; 1960–1985Pre-tax income share accruing to the third quintile (note: measure of equality) Cross-section; OLS, 2SLS
= 74/81; 1970–1978Coefficient of variation; Theil's index; Gini; share of income of the poorest 40% to the share of income of the richest 20%United Nations Indicator of Social Development; ; Cross-section; OLS, WLS, 2SLS
) = 67; 1960–1985Combined share of the third and fourth quintiles ; Cross-section; OLS, 2SLS
= 31; 1970–2010Gini; bottom inequality; top inequalityOECD income distribution datasetPanel; Sys-GMM
= 153; 1960–2009GiniSWIIDPanel; Sys-GMM
= 164; 1965–2014GiniSWIIDPanel; two-step Sys-GMM
Positive effect = 46; 1960–1990GiniDSPanel; FE, RE
= 45; 1966–1995GiniDSPanel; FE, RE, Diff-GMM
= 123; 1960–2010GiniSWIIDPanel; LSDV
It depends
 Controls = 87/66; 1960–1992Gini; land distributionDSCross-section; OLS
 Level of income = 84; 1965–1995Gini; quintile sharesDSPanel; 3SLS
= 102/23; 1960–2000Gini; percentile ratiosWIID; LISPanel; Sys-GMM
 Non-linear effects = 45; 1965–1995GiniDSPanel; RE, GMM, Kernel regression
 Profile of inequality = 21; 1975–2000Gini; top-end and bottom-end inequalityLISPanel; Sys-GMM
 Time = 106; 1965–2005GiniDS; WIIDPanel; Diff-GMM, Sys-GMM

Notes : DS, Deininger and Squire (1996) ; LIS, Luxemburg Income Study; OLS, ordinary least squares; 2SLS, two-stage least squares; WLS, weighted least squares; 3SLS, three-stage least squares; LSDV, least squares dummy variable; FE, fixed effects; RE, random effects; Sys-GMM, system GMM; Diff-GMM, difference GMM.

Source : Authors’ elaboration, inspired from Cingano (2014) and Neves and Silva (2014) .

The aim was to estimate the coefficient of the income inequality variable δ , and most of these studies found a negative effect of inequality on growth. Persson and Tabellini (1994) obtained evidence for this effect using historical panel data and postwar cross-sectional analysis. Both the studies by Alesina and Rodrik (1994) and Clarke (1995) confirm this relationship using data from, among others, Jain (1975) and Lecaillon et al. (1984) . Clarke (1995) showed that this was robust to different measures and empirical specifications.

Given the challenges imposed by scarce data, some authors turned to an analysis between states in the United States. Partridge (1997) tested the robustness of the Persson and Tabellini (1994) findings, and the results suggested a positive link between inequality and subsequent growth when considering either the Gini coefficient or the share of income of the middle quintile. 23 Using tax data at the state level for the period 1940–1980, Panizza (2002) warned that both the data and the methodology used led to significant differences in the estimated coefficients for the effect of inequality on growth.

While the quality and reliability of the data are important challenges pertaining to early studies ( Knowles 2005 ), the introduction of an improved and expanded dataset by Deininger and Squire (1996) led to a surge in new studies using panel estimators. In contrast with previous work, these studies found a positive link between inequality and growth. Li and Zou (1998) showed that the coefficient for lagged Gini has a positive sign and is significant in most growth regressions. Forbes (2000) confirmed this result using similar data and generalized method of moments (GMM) estimators. 24 Still, using the same dataset, Deininger and Squire (1998) found a negative effect of initial income inequality on growth, although the coefficient lost significance once they add regional dummies to the specification.

Offering a starting point to reconcile the differing views, some studies have argued that the relationship between inequality and growth depends on other factors. According to Barro (2000) , the effect of inequality on growth depends on the level of income of the country: panel evidence suggests growth-enhancing effects of inequality in richer countries (GDP per capita: above $2,000, 1985 US dollars) and negative effects in poorer countries (below $2,000). Moreover, Banerjee and Duflo (2003) have raised concerns about the functional form used in the literature, arguing against using a linear specification for the relationship between inequality and growth. Their empirical work suggests an inverted U-shaped function between changes in inequality and lower future growth rates. Using a small sample of industrialized countries, Voitchovsky (2005) showed empirical support for the hypothesis that the profile of inequality influenced its relationship with growth: top-end inequality seems to have a positive effect and bottom-end inequality a negative effect.

The debate has continued in the literature ever since. Cingano (2014) lends support to a negative effect of inequality on growth using data from the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) income distribution dataset. Additionally, the author suggests that reducing inequality by focusing on income disparities at the bottom of the income distribution has a greater positive effect on growth than by focusing on the top of the distribution. The Castelló-Climent (2010) results concur with this when considering the full sample of countries, but the results also find support for the argument of a differentiated effect according to the level of development. Halter, Oechslin, and Zweimüller (2014) argue that there is a time dimension to the link between inequality and growth, showing a positive coefficient for the current Gini coefficient and a negative coefficient for lagged Gini.

Some studies have used data from an additional dataset proposed by Solt (2009) , the Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID). Yet, results also mirror the lack of consensus of earlier work. Applying system GMM, work from the International Monetary Fund finds a robust negative effect of inequality on growth ( Ostry, Berg, and Tsangarides 2014 ; Berg et al. 2018 ). While Gründler and Scheuermeyer (2018) concur with this result, Jäntti, Pirtillä, and Rönkkö (2020) raise concerns about the results in Berg et al. (2018) , resulting from the use of the SWIID dataset. El-Shagi and Shao (2019) criticize previous studies using system GMM and argue for the advantages of using a least-squares dummy variable estimation instead. In contrast, their results show a positive effect of inequality on growth over the medium term, primarily driven by market-based inequality.

Barro's (2000) view that the effect depends on the level of development in the country, confirmed in later analysis by the same author using the WIID dataset ( Barro 2008 ), has also been verified in some recent work. Gründler and Scheuermeyer (2018) see a negative and significant marginal effect of net inequality on growth in poor economies, which is, however, nonsignificant in high-income countries. 25

Channels of transmission

As discussed in section “How Inequality Affects Growth,” the theory proposes different channels through which inequality may affect growth. Although these specific mechanisms have received less attention in empirical work, we highlight the main findings, also summarized in  table 2 .

Summary of empirical evidence on the different channels linking inequality and growth

HypothesisChannelEmpirical evidence
High inequality is growth enhancingSavingsSome evidence using household micro-data, but mixed results using cross-country aggregate data ( , 1482). rejects this hypothesis.
High inequality has a negative effect on growthCredit market imperfectionsSupport in , to some extent in ) and in .
FertilityConfirmed by , ), , and .
Government expenditure and taxationThe fiscal policy channel received less support by ) and it was rejected by . showed support for this hypothesis in the short run but not in the long run.
Structure of demandNo specific empirical evidence on this channel.
Sociopolitical instability and rent seekingSupport in ), , and .
HypothesisChannelEmpirical evidence
High inequality is growth enhancingSavingsSome evidence using household micro-data, but mixed results using cross-country aggregate data ( , 1482). rejects this hypothesis.
High inequality has a negative effect on growthCredit market imperfectionsSupport in , to some extent in ) and in .
FertilityConfirmed by , ), , and .
Government expenditure and taxationThe fiscal policy channel received less support by ) and it was rejected by . showed support for this hypothesis in the short run but not in the long run.
Structure of demandNo specific empirical evidence on this channel.
Sociopolitical instability and rent seekingSupport in ), , and .

Starting with the savings channel, while there is evidence of a positive link between inequality and personal savings when using household micro-data, studies based on cross-country aggregate data have found mixed results (see references in Thorbecke and Charumilind, 2002 ). Barro (2000) found that the investment ratio does not depend significantly on inequality. The channel via market imperfections and borrowing constraints found support in Deininger and Squire (1998) , who added that the effect through the investment in human capital seems more important than that via physical capital, as well as to some extent in Perotti (1996 ). 26 This channel also suggests that asset inequality matters for growth ( Ravallion 2001 , 1810), shown in both Birdsall and Londoño (1997) and Deininger and Olinto (2000) .

Moreover, there is published support for the channels related to sociopolitical instability ( Perotti 1996 ). Using data from a sample of seventy-one countries over the period 1960–1985, Alesina and Perotti (1996) found that a wealthy middle class is associated with lower levels of political instability, conducive to higher investment. Keefer and Knack (2002) showed evidence of a negative effect of inequality on growth and suggested that property rights are an important channel for this relationship.

Perotti (1996 ) confirmed the link between inequality and growth via fertility. Testing the same hypothesis, de la Croix and Doepke (2003) used Deininger and Squire's (1996) improved dataset and showed that the negative and significant effect of initial inequality on subsequent growth does not survive the inclusion of the differential fertility variable, which is negative and significant. They interpret this as meaning that the differential fertility is an important factor explaining the link between inequality and growth.

The fiscal policy channel received less support by Perotti (1996 ) while Persson and Tabellini (1994) also obtained coefficients with the expected sign but statistically insignificant for the links from inequality to redistributive policies and from redistribution to growth. Sylwester (2000) showed results from cross-country analysis that indicated that higher inequality is associated with higher subsequent expenditures for public education relative to GDP, which in turn has a negative effect on current growth but a long-term positive impact.

Recent studies have shown evidence that corroborates the theoretical effects via human capital accumulation ( Berg et al. 2018 ), via credit market imperfections ( Gründler and Scheuermeyer 2018 ), and via fertility ( Berg et al. 2018 ; Gründler and Scheuermeyer 2018 ) as channels through which inequality affects growth. Using data from twenty-one OECD countries over the period 1870–2011, Madsen, Islam, and Doucouliagos (2018) find support for the hypothesis that income inequality affects growth through different channels, namely savings, investment, education, and ideas production. Additionally, they concur with the arguments on differentiated effects. Although the negative impacts are significant in financially underdeveloped countries, there is little effect of inequality on the four outcomes in countries with highly developed financial markets.

Education and Health

In a recent paper, Castells-Quintana, Royuela, and Thiel (2019) estimated the effects of the Gini coefficient on the human development index (HDI) and found a negative effect in the long run, whereas in the short run the results change for different components of the index: a positive effect on income and a negative effect on educational outcomes. Moreover, they concur with the aforementioned studies that found distinct effects depending on the level of development. We are not aware of any other studies pursuing a similar analysis for the HDI, but in the remainder of this section, we discuss the empirical results on the link between inequality and education and health. We summarize the main conclusions in  table 3 .

Summary of empirical evidence on the different hypotheses on the effects of inequality on education and health

OutcomeEffectEmpirical evidence
EducationInequality affects expenditure on educationIn contrast with theory, suggests that a high level of inequality is correlated with higher spending for public education.
Inequality affects education enrolment and attainmentSeveral studies find a negative link between inequality and secondary school enrolment ( ; ; ; ; ; ). A study from the United States links an increase in inequality with an increase in the gap in the educational attainment between rich and poor ( ).
HealthInequality affects the health of all individualsThere is strong support from Wilkinson and Pickett in different studies ( ; ) and weak support in . Concerns have been raised in reviews by ), , , and .
Inequality affects the population health but not necessarily of all individualsStrong support exists for the absolute income hypothesis, resulting from the concave relationship between average income and average health ( ).
No evidence exists for the relative income hypothesis; that is, that there is an effect on health resulting from individuals comparing their income with that of others ( ).
The hypothesis that what matters is the relative position of the individual in the income distribution has not been tested ( ).
OutcomeEffectEmpirical evidence
EducationInequality affects expenditure on educationIn contrast with theory, suggests that a high level of inequality is correlated with higher spending for public education.
Inequality affects education enrolment and attainmentSeveral studies find a negative link between inequality and secondary school enrolment ( ; ; ; ; ; ). A study from the United States links an increase in inequality with an increase in the gap in the educational attainment between rich and poor ( ).
HealthInequality affects the health of all individualsThere is strong support from Wilkinson and Pickett in different studies ( ; ) and weak support in . Concerns have been raised in reviews by ), , , and .
Inequality affects the population health but not necessarily of all individualsStrong support exists for the absolute income hypothesis, resulting from the concave relationship between average income and average health ( ).
No evidence exists for the relative income hypothesis; that is, that there is an effect on health resulting from individuals comparing their income with that of others ( ).
The hypothesis that what matters is the relative position of the individual in the income distribution has not been tested ( ).

Although there is an extensive body of empirical literature examining education as a determinant of income inequality, the evidence on the link from income inequality to educational outcomes is scarcer ( Thorbecke and Charumilind 2002 , 1488; Gutiérrez and Tanaka 2009 , 56). However, there is evidence that income inequality is reproduced in inequality in education, both in terms of achievements in primary and secondary school and in terms of access to tertiary education (see Buchmann and Hannum 2001 and references in Stewart 2016 ).

Regarding the links proposed in the theoretical work reviewed in the previous section, Sylwester (2000) reported a positive link between inequality and public expenditures on education. Considering the demand side, some studies have found a negative link between inequality and secondary school enrolment. Flug, Spilimbergo, and Wachtenheim (1998) and Easterly (2007) used cross-country analysis, while Esposito and Villaseñor (2018) used data from the 2010 Mexican Census. The study by Madsen, Islam, and Doucouliagos (2018) shows a negative impact of inequality on the combined primary, secondary, and tertiary school enrolment rate in financially underdeveloped countries (using a sample from OECD). Concurring with these findings, Berg et al. (2018) show a negative correlation between inequality and human capital, measured as the average years of primary and secondary schooling. Checchi (2003) provided support for the link between inequality and growth via borrowing constraints and showed evidence of a negative effect of inequality on access to secondary education. 27 Finally, using data from the United States for the period 1970–1990, Mayer (2001) found that the increase in inequality aggravates the gap in educational attainment between rich and poor children.

Given that the literature is extensive and stems from different fields of literature (including, public health), we summarize the main conclusions from different reviews, which distinguish between aggregate level and multilevel studies as well as cross-country and within-country empirical analyses. 28 Wagstaff and van Doorslaer (2000) highlighted that studies at the population level are limited in what they can reveal about the effects on individual health and that data at the individual level are required to disentangle the effects of the different hypotheses described in section “Inequality negatively affects health.” Still, existing evidence on these different channels remains inconclusive.

Lynch et al. (2004) found weak support for a direct effect of income inequality on health, although inequality contributes directly to some health outcomes (e.g., homicides). Furthermore, they underlined that the reduction of income inequality via income rises for the more disadvantaged contributes to improved health of these individuals and increases average population health. Rowlingson (2011) concludes that there is some evidence of an independent effect on health and social problems, but in line with Subramanian and Kawachi (2004) , also highlights the lack of consensus in the results and the need for further work. Still, from a systematic review of 155 published peer-review studies, Wilkinson and Pickett (2006) concluded that there is a link between greater income inequality and poorer health. Almost ten years later, the authors provided further support for the existence of a causal link between income inequality and health and reinforced their argument of the size of status and social class differences as an important mechanism ( Pickett and Wilkinson 2015 ).

The conclusions from the economics literature have pointed to no evidence of a causal relationship ( Nolan and Valenzuela 2019 ). From a detailed review of the literature, Deaton (2003 , 150) argued that “the stories about income inequality affecting health are stronger than the evidence” and that there is no robust evidence showing that income inequality in itself is an important determinant of population health, although it had effects through poverty. The review in Leigh, Jencks, and Smeeding (2011) concurred. However, they warned that given the data challenges and the limitations of the methods used to test the link between inequality and health, one should not jump to definite conclusions. Focusing on morbidity and mortality, the comprehensive review of empirical literature by O'Donnell, van Doorslaer, and van Ourti (2015) concludes that even though population health is negatively associated with income inequality, there is little evidence to support the hypothesis of a negative impact of income inequality on health.

We start this section by noting that the focus on voting underlying the political economy mechanism linking inequality and growth suggests that the effects should be observed in democracies ( Houle 2015 , 143). Thus, some of the early empirical literature on the relationship between inequality and growth also tested whether this effect was dependent on the regime type (e.g., see Alesina and Rodrik 1994 ; Persson and Tabellini 1994 ; Clarke 1995 ; Perotti 1996 ; Deininger and Squire 1998 ).

The results were mixed. Persson and Tabellini (1994) suggested that the negative link between inequality and growth is only present in democracies and that the transmission channel through government redistributive policies should be further investigated. However, Perotti (1996 ) counterargued that, although the data showed a stronger relationship between equality and growth in democracies, the effect of the democracy variable did not appear to be robust. Further criticism was advanced by Knack and Keefer (1997) , who, after some regime reclassification and deletion of doubtful observations, concluded that there is no evidence of a differential effect of inequality on growth in democracies and non-democracies. Østby (2013) and Stewart (2016) argued that there is compelling evidence for the link between horizontal inequality (i.e., inequality among groups) and civil conflict as well as other forms of group violence. However, more recent reviews suggest that the evidence on the link between inequality and political violence is mixed ( Lengfelder 2019 ).

We now turn to what the empirical evidence on the government outcomes described in section “How inequality affects democratic governance” shows, and summarize the main conclusions in  table 4 . Using data from two panels on the periods 1950–1990 and 1850–1980, Boix (2003) showed empirical evidence for a positive link between equality (proxied by an adjusted Gini coefficient) and democratization and, particularly, democratic consolidation. In an extension of this analysis, Boix and Stokes (2003) concluded that economic equality, proxied by farm ownership (distribution of agricultural property) and literacy rates (quality of human capital), has a positive effect on both the probability of a democratic transition and the stability of democracy.

Summary of empirical evidence on the effects of inequality on different governance outcomes

OutcomeEmpirical evidence
DemocracyMixed results are found for the effect through redistributive policies. While some studies find support for a negative link between inequality and democratization ( ) and democratic consolidation ( ), others have challenged the robustness of the effect of inequality on democracy (e.g., ; ) and suggested that this effect is conditional on certain factors, such as the state of the macroeconomy ( ).
Institutional qualityThere is some evidence of a negative link between inequality and institutional quality ( ; ), and corruption in particular ( ), but there is a need for further research ( ).
Political participationRecent evidence from developed economies suggests a negative effect of inequality on political participation ( ; ; ), support for democracy ( ; ), and political inequality ( ), but there is limited support for an impact on electoral turnout ( ; ).
OutcomeEmpirical evidence
DemocracyMixed results are found for the effect through redistributive policies. While some studies find support for a negative link between inequality and democratization ( ) and democratic consolidation ( ), others have challenged the robustness of the effect of inequality on democracy (e.g., ; ) and suggested that this effect is conditional on certain factors, such as the state of the macroeconomy ( ).
Institutional qualityThere is some evidence of a negative link between inequality and institutional quality ( ; ), and corruption in particular ( ), but there is a need for further research ( ).
Political participationRecent evidence from developed economies suggests a negative effect of inequality on political participation ( ; ; ), support for democracy ( ; ), and political inequality ( ), but there is limited support for an impact on electoral turnout ( ; ).

Others found low support for a significant link between the two (e.g., Bollen and Jackman 1985 ). 29 Barro (1999) showed a negative, but only marginally significant coefficient for the effect of inequality on democracy, proxied as electoral rights and civil liberties, for the period 1972–1995. However, when entered alongside the share of income accruing to the middle class, the coefficient is nonsignificant. The empirical analysis in Houle (2009) went against previous results on the negative link between inequality and democracy and showed a weak positive and nonsignificant relationship. Using the capital share of the value added in the industrial sector as a measure of inequality to overcome the data limitations in previous studies, the author also did not find support for Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) ’s inverted U-shaped relationship but rather for a weakly U-shaped one.

More recently, Haggard and Kaufman (2012) used causal process observation to examine the association between inequality and transitions to and from democratic rule and found limited evidence supporting the link via distributive conflict between elites and masses. Additionally, the evidence in Scheve and Stasavage (2017) does not support the hypothesis of a link between wealth inequality and democracy. Dorsch and Maarek (2020) offer an explanation for the abundancy of null results found for the link between inequality and democratization, showing that higher levels of inequality are associated with higher probabilities of democratic improvements following economic downturns (“windows of opportunity”). However, following growth periods, the effect of inequality is null or small and negative.

Considering a broader approach to governance, we briefly refer to the literature linking inequality and institutional quality. 30 Both Easterly (2007) and Chong and Gradstein (2007 ) tested the causal relationship between these variables using an instrumental variables approach and system GMM methods, respectively, and found support for the effect of inequality on institutions. More recently, Kotschy and Sunde (2017) showed evidence of the importance of equality as a determinant of the effect of democratic institutions on institutional quality, measured by an index of economic freedom and an indicator of civil liberties. 31 It has also been shown that countries with more income inequality have more corruption ( Jong-Sung and Khagram 2005 ), and, in particular, survey evidence links perceptions of corruption and inequality to lower political trust ( Uslaner 2017 ).

Finally, there is evidence from advanced industrial democracies of a negative link between inequality and political participation ( Lengfelder 2019 ). Solt (2008) showed a negative effect of economic inequality on political engagement, namely political interest, the frequency of political discussion, and participation in elections among all citizens except the richest, using data from advanced industrial countries. Using cross-sectional data from OECD countries and within-country data for Germany and a range of methods, the recent study by Schäfer and Schwander (2019) finds support for the negative link between economic inequality and political participation. Relatedly, empirical work suggests that economic inequality harms support for democracy (e.g., Andersen 2012 ; Krieckhaus et al. 2014 ) and political inequality (e.g., Houle 2018 ). Still, there appears to be limited evidence of an effect of inequality on electoral turnout ( Stockemer and Scruggs 2012 ; Cancela and Geys 2016 ).

The lack of consensus in the literature, especially about the effect of inequality on growth, is notable. What explains this divergence, and what can be done to contribute to the existing knowledge? In this section, we discuss the key empirical challenges of estimating the effects of inequality: data quality and availability, conceptual and measurement issues, and the methodological difficulties of dealing with confounding variables and endogeneity.

Data quality and availability

Early studies drew on secondary datasets provided, for example, by the World Bank ( Jain 1975 ) or the International Labour Office ( Lecaillon et al. 1984 ). The expanded dataset proposed by Deininger and Squire (1996) was crucial in opening possibilities for panel methods. Additionally, databases offering secondary data compilations on income inequality provided by the United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research, WIID (based on household surveys), and SWIID, developed by Solt (2020) and resulting from multiple imputations of the WIID data, have been frequently used in empirical studies. The World Inequality Database ( WID.world 2017 ) has emerged as an additional database providing data on income shares captured by top income groups.

Atkinson and Brandolini (2001 , 2009 ) and Ferreira, Lustig, and Teles (2015) offer comprehensive analyses on secondary datasets on income distribution, drawing attention to issues of data quality and consistency linked to differences in the definitions used, sources of data, and the processing used to obtain “ready-made” income distribution statistics. 32 Atkinson and Brandolini (2001 ) focused mainly on the Deininger and Squire dataset and on data for OECD member countries. Jenkins (2015) follows a similar line of reasoning and compares the WIID and the SWIID, noting that for the latter it is also critical to consider issues relating to the quality of imputations. Jäntti, Pirtillä, and Rönkkö (2020) stress that, in most developing countries, the actual redistribution is only rarely measured, so figures in the SWIID reflect questionable imputations.

As demonstrated in Atkinson and Brandolini (2001 , 2009 ) and Jenkins (2015) , issues of noncomparability have consequences for econometric analysis and for trends over time. Voitchovsky (2011 , 566) warns that data scarcity and limitations in terms of data availability may lead to a trade-off between sources of bias and precision in inequality studies. Ravallion (2001 , 1809) notes, however, that measurement errors, including those resulting from comparability problems, will have a greater impact on analyses that allow for country fixed-effects rather than on standard growth regressions given that the signal-to-noise ratio is likely to be low for changes in measured inequality.

The challenges are even more striking for tests that require data at the individual level, namely those related to the relative hypotheses linking inequality to health. These hypotheses also lead to questions about the appropriate reference groups—how they are defined and formed—as well as in terms of endogeneity, as the position of the individual in relation to the reference may be affected by group membership ( O'Donnell, van Doorslaer, and van Ourti 2015 , 1505).

Concept and measurement of inequality

Issues of concept and measurement are also consequential. 33 Atkinson and Brandolini (2001 ) provide a useful summary of eight parameters to be chosen when defining an income distribution, among which are the unit of observation, concept of resource (e.g., income versus expenditure), and tax treatment of income. These closely link to measurement choices. Different mechanisms require a specific concept of inequality and this should be reflected in the measure of inequality used in the empirical analysis ( Voitchovsky 2011 , 567). Additionally, different parts of the distribution receive importance depending on the inequality measure used, and even the concept of income is open to measurement issues ( Deaton 2003 , 135).

Knowles's (2005) account of the relationship between inequality and growth illustrates these concerns. The author warns that the results in previous studies should be regarded with some degree of caution given that they failed to measure inequality in a consistent manner, mixing measures of the distributions of income before and after tax and the distribution of expenditure. Considering six different measures of inequality (three Gini coefficients and three top ten income shares), a recent study by Blotevogel et al. (2020) shows that the choice of the inequality indicator has important implications for the results obtained in empirical analysis, namely when considering different transmission channels between inequality and growth. In terms of the link between inequality and democratic governance, there is a concern that frequently used measures do not capture interclass inequality, which precludes the testing of theoretical hypotheses that hinge on this ( Houle 2015 , 147).

Criticism has also been directed at specific measures, in particular the widely used Gini coefficient. In light of the observations above, Gini coefficients will provide different information depending on how they are calculated, for example, if based on net income or on gross income ( Houle 2015 , 147). Moreover, some have argued that the use of absolute rather than relative measures might better capture perceptions of inequality on the ground (e.g., Bosmans et al. 2014 ; Atkinson and Brandolini 2004 ; Niño-Zarazúa, Roope, and Tarp 2017 ).

Estimation methods

A review of empirical studies on the inequality–growth link highlights contrasting findings between the early cross-country studies and those that employed panel estimation techniques, after the Deininger and Squire (1998) dataset became available. Some explanations have been advanced for this divergence.

Measurement error may affect the estimation results in cross-country estimation (country- or regional-specific measurement error), and also in panel data estimation, given that inequality tends to be persistent over time; thus, this method relies on more limited time-series variation in the data. The coefficients in cross-country studies may be biased due to time-invariant omitted variables ( Voitchovsky 2011 , 565), while if we consider that inequality is related to underlying determinants of development that are persistent, then fixed-effect estimates may be biased upward when considering long-run effects ( Castells-Quintana, Royuela, and Thiel 2019 , 454).

Additional explanations included the argument for the misspecification of the linearity in the effect of inequality and growth ( Banerjee and Duflo 2003 ) and the suggestion that the two methods capture different time effects, given the short- and long-term lag structures in panel and cross-country analyses, respectively ( Voitchovsky 2011 , 565).

Finally, several concerns have been raised regarding the use of different instruments to tackle reverse causality in the relationship between inequality and growth (see Easterly 2007 ) as well as health ( O'Donnell, van Doorslaer, and van Ourti 2015 , 1505) and democracy ( Houle 2015 , 147). While different attempts have been made using instrumental variable approaches, finding a valid instrument for inequality is certainly not straightforward. Furthermore, even if GMM has often been used to try to tackle these issues, Roodman (2009) warns about the risk of instrument proliferation and the possibility for generating false-positive results. As an illustration, he reexamined the analysis in Forbes (2000) and raised concerns over the positive effect of inequality on growth found in the original paper.

This review combined the different theoretical hypotheses concerning the impact of inequality on three core socioeconomic and political outcomes in a simplified framework and highlighted the mixed empirical evidence. We summarize the main conclusions as follows. First, in line with previous findings, the debate on whether there is a positive or a negative effect on growth remains open, with recent studies mirroring the disagreement in decades of empirical work. With the exception of the classical approach, most of the transmission channels between inequality and growth point to a negative effect of inequality. However, the evidence from reduced-form equations is not consensual and the channels of transmission have received less attention.

Second, while there seems to be some consensus in the evidence that there is a negative link between inequality and secondary school enrolment, there is need for further research in terms of other education outcomes. Although theory generally points toward a negative effect of inequality on health, the existing evidence does not provide clear support to this relationship, in the economic literature in particular, and there is a lot to be uncovered in terms of the mechanisms of transmission at the individual level. Third, theoretical predictions and empirical evidence show mixed results for the effects of inequality on democracy and political participation.

In understanding the diversity and divergence in theoretical and empirical results, a number of empirical challenges remain. Problems with data quality and availability are well understood in the literature, as are those related to the concept and measurement of inequality, and the shortcomings of different estimation methods.

In terms of potential avenues for future work, our review points for one to the value of further attention to different transmission channels (highlighted in  figure 1 ). We first propose a methodological suggestion. While advances in econometric analysis will shed light on the analysis across countries, this could be complemented with the use of experimental work to understand specific channels in particular contexts. While not a substitute for empirical cross-country analysis, experiments can be employed to understand microlevel behavior. The controlled nature of this work avoids biases in econometric studies and mitigates issues of endogeneity and measurement errors.

The second avenue relates to the focus of the analysis. While this review mainly concentrated on cross-country analysis, there is indication that disaggregating the level of analysis might provide useful insights in terms of channels of transmission and underlying cases. For instance, it might be that in Africa, competition over natural resources is the main driver of inequality and in turn slower growth, while in Latin America, inequality may be the main driver for political instability. Furthering regional and country-specific analysis might help dig deeper into these effects.

Finally, despite the existing efforts to compile new—and improve on the existing—secondary datasets, problems persist with the available data. Thus, in light of the importance of data availability and reliability for the analysis of the trends and effects of inequality, we stress that earlier calls for more and better data continue to be both relevant and important for progress in our search for better understanding of the impact of inequality.

Equity here refers to equality of opportunities to pursue a life of one's choosing and protection from extreme deprivation in outcomes ( World Bank 2006 , 18–19). Efficiency refers to economic efficiency, underpinning economic growth ( Thorbecke 2016 ).

Given the multidimensionality of inequality and that its effects are in focus in different disciplines, we follow an interdisciplinary approach. Yet, in the empirical section, we focus on strands of work that employ similar (quantitative) methodologies.

We focus on the main arguments that have attracted attention in these disciplines and have made a concerted effort to address the gender citation gap that exists, for instance, in international relations scholarship (e.g., Maliniak, Powers, and Walter 2013 ).

Throughout, we refer to “income inequality” and “inequality” interchangeably. Although we recognize the multidimensionality of the concept, we focus on literature considering income inequality, which remains a dominant measure ( Stewart 2016 , 64), and refer to more extensive work on other aspects, in particular, the relevance of poverty rates (e.g., Ravallion 2012 ), inequality of opportunity (e.g., Marrero and Rodriguez 2013 ; Ferreira et al. 2018 ), gender inequality (e.g., Bandiera and Natraj 2013 ; Kabeer 2015 ), and horizontal inequalities ( Stewart 2005 ).

We use “growth” and “economic growth” interchangeably.

We highlight that there is expanding work on different facets of economic performance, such as growth volatility (e.g., Iyigun and Owen 2004 ) or the occurrence of crises (e.g., Morelli and Atkinson 2015 ).

Kuznets (1955) argued that the early stages of the development process would experience rising inequality, which would then fall as the country reached higher levels of per capita income. This relationship, known as the “Kuznets curve,” and other work looking at this direction of causality are not covered here.

See also a review of early studies in Bénabou (1996) and Aghion, Caroli, and García-Peñalosa (1999 ) and a more recent overview in Ehrhart (2009) .

Sandmo (2015) reviews the history of theories of income distribution, from Adam Smith until the 1970s.

For a summary of theoretical work on the choice between a public and a private education system, see García-Peñalosa (1995) .

Gutiérrez and Tanaka (2009) review previous theoretical models.

Additional mechanisms relate to social comparison and include relative deprivation and gratification in the context of neighborhood and school effects, and economic segregation ( Mayer 2001 ). The first refers to the fact that people compare themselves with those who are more disadvantaged, which in the case of children can lead to feeling less willing to study or stay in school and in the case of parents can cause stress and alienation. The second suggests that increases in inequality are likely to lead to more geographic segregation as the rich and poor have less in common. See Mayer (2001 , 4–7) for more details.

See Deaton (2003 ) and Lynch et al. (2004) for detailed descriptions of the emergence of debate on the link between income inequality and health.

We do not cover studies on the link between inequality and homicides and between inequality and life satisfaction and happiness ( Graham 2014 ).

Lynch et al. (2004 , 15–16) refer to additional nuances, related to the effects of inequality through psychosocial processes and through the differential accumulation of exposures deriving from material sources rather than from perceptions of disadvantage. They also mention the weak and strong versions of this hypothesis proposed by Mellor and Milyo (2002) .

For a study on the effects of inequality on group participation, see La Ferrara (2002) .

Thorbecke and Charumilind (2002) review the evidence and causal mechanisms linking inequality and crime.

For a review of the theoretical arguments developed earlier, see Bollen and Jackman (1985) .

This line of reasoning can be linked to the work by Glaeser, Scheinkman, and Shleifer (2003) mentioned in section “How inequality affects growth,” which discusses the negative effects of inequality on growth through institutional subversion (including corruption).

For further details, see Solt (2008 , 48–50).

It is also useful to refer here to studies examining the impact of inequality on electoral turnout (e.g., Stockemer and Scruggs 2012 ), support for democracy (e.g., Andersen 2012 ; Krieckhaus et al. 2014 ), and, more generally, political inequality (e.g., Houle 2018 ).

A more complete list of studies is available from the authors.

Studies in the 1990s also focus on determining whether there was a differential effect of inequality on growth in democracies and non-democracies ( Persson and Tabellini 1994 ; Alesina and Rodrik 1994 ; Perotti 1996 ; Clarke 1995 ; Deininger and Squire 1998 ). We discuss this in Section ”Governance.”

Two recent studies build on Forbes (2000) , attempting to overcome some of the remaining estimation challenges. Aiyar and Ebeke (2020) draw attention to the importance of considering equality of opportunity and find empirical support for their hypothesis that the negative effect of income inequality is greater in countries with low levels of equality of opportunity (measured by intergenerational mobility). Scholl and Klasen (2019) replicate Forbes’ (2000) finding but show that it disappears once they control for the experience of transition countries.

Islam and McGillivray (2020) highlight the increasing interest in wealth inequality and investigate its effect on growth using wealth data from Forbes Magazine and Credit Suisse over the period 2000–2012. The results suggest a negative effect.

Perotti (1996 ) empirically tested the channels of transmission, estimating different structural models: first, using each of these channels in a growth model and, then, estimating the effects of inequality on each of the channels.

With the exception of Flug, Spilimbergo, and Wachtenheim (1998) , all these studies employ the Gini coefficient as one of their measures of inequality. Flug, Spilimbergo, and Wachtenheim (1998) used the ratio of the income shares of the top quintile to the bottom two quintiles of the population, and the shares of income accruing to the top quintile and the lowest quintile were used, respectively, by Easterly (2007) and Checchi (2003) . In their robustness checks, Esposito and Villaseñor (2018) used the Atkinson and Theil indices.

We do not offer a comprehensive overview of the measures used in the literature. According to the review in Lynch et al. (2004) , the majority of the studies employ the Gini coefficient or different shares of income. In the list of studies reviewed by these authors, we counted sixty-nine out of ninety-eight using the Gini as (one of) the measure(s) of inequality.

The review of the initial studies in Bollen and Jackman (1985) argued that problems of specification, measurement, and sample composition led to inconclusive results in the existing empirical analyses.

Savoia, Easaw, and McKay (2010) reviewed the arguments linking inequality to institutional quality directly and via democracy and argued that the limited existing work suggests a negative link between inequality and institutions, noting there is a need for further research.

When considering the role of governance (using different indicators), the estimates in Islam and McGillivray (2020) indicate that improved governance may contribute to reduced wealth inequality and higher growth.

See also discussions of these shortcomings in Deaton (2003 ), Voitchovsky (2011) , and Houle (2015) .

As illustrated in section “What the empirical evidence says,” issues of concept and measurement for our outcome variables also matter to consideration of theories and hypothesis testing.

This study was prepared within the project “The impacts of inequality on growth, human development, and governance - @EQUAL.” Support by the Novo Nordisk Foundation Grant NNF19SA0060072 is acknowledged.

We are grateful to the editors and three anonymous referees for insightful and useful suggestions. We thank Anustup Kundu for excellent research assistance as well as Klarizze Puzon, Miguel Niño-Zarazúa, Carlos Gradín, and participants at an internal project workshop for valuable comments. The usual caveats apply.

Acemoglu Daron , Robinson James A. . 2006 . Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy . Cambridge, MA : Cambridge University Press .

Google Scholar

Google Preview

Aghion Philippe , Caroli Eve , García-Peñalosa Cecilia . 1999 . “ Inequality and Economic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories .” Journal of Economic Literature 37 ( 4 ): 1615 – 60 .

Aiyar Shekhar , Ebeke Christian . 2020 . “ Inequality of Opportunity, Inequality of Income and Economic Growth .” World Development 136 : 105115 .

Alesina Alberto , Rodrik Dani . 1994 . “ Distributive Politics and Economic Growth .” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 ( 2 ): 465 – 90 .

Alesina Alberto , Perotti Roberto . 1996 . “ Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment .” European Economic Review 40 ( 6 ): 1203 – 28 .

Andersen Robert . 2012 . “ Support for Democracy in Cross-National Perspective: The Detrimental Effect of Economic Inequality .” Research in Social Stratification and Mobility 30 ( 4 ): 389 – 402 .

Ansell Ben , Samuels David . 2010 . “ Inequality and Democratization: A Contractarian Approach .” Comparative Political Studies 43 ( 12 ): 1543 – 74 .

Atkinson Anthony B. , Brandolini Andrea . 2001 . “ Promise and Pitfalls in the Use of ‘Secondary’ Data-Sets: Income Inequality in OECD Countries as a Case Study .” Journal of Economic Literature 39 ( 3 ): 771 – 99 .

Atkinson Anthony B. , Brandolini Andrea . 2004 . “ Global World Inequality: Absolute, Relative or Intermediate? ” Paper prepared for the 28th General Conference of The International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, Cork, Ireland, August 22–28, 2004 .

Atkinson Anthony B. , Brandolini Andrea . 2009 . “ On Data: A Case Study of the Evolution of Income Inequality across Time and across Countries .” Cambridge Journal of Economics 33 ( 3 ): 381 – 404 .

Bandiera Oriana , Natraj Ashwini . 2013 . “ Does Gender Inequality Hinder Development and Economic Growth? Evidence and Policy Implications .” The World Bank Research Observer 28 ( 1 ): 2 – 21 .

Banerjee Abhijit V. , Duflo Esther . 2003 . “ Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say? ” Journal of Economic Growth 8 ( 3 ): 267 – 99 .

Barro Robert J. 1999 . “ Determinants of Democracy .” Journal of Political Economy 107 ( S6 ): S158 – 83 .

Barro Robert J. . 2000 . “ Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries .” Journal of Economic Growth 5 : 5 – 32 .

Barro Robert J. . 2008 . “ Inequality and Growth Revisited .” ADB Working Paper Series on Regional Economic Integration 11. Asian Development Bank (ADB), Philippines. Accessed November 16, 2020. https://www.adb.org/sites/default/files/publication/28468/wp11-inequality-growth-revisited.pdf .

Bénabou Roland . 1996 . “ Inequality and Growth .” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1996 , Volume 11, edited by Bernanke Ben S. , Rotemberg Julio J. , 11 – 92 . Cambridge, MA : MIT Press .

Bénabou Roland . 2000 . “ Unequal Societies: Income Distribution and the Social Contract .” American Economic Review 90 ( 1 ): 96 – 129 .

Berg Andrew , Ostry Jonathan D. , Sangarides Charalambs G. , Yakhshilikov Yorbol . 2018 . “ Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth: New Evidence .” Journal of Economic Growth 23 ( 4 ): 259 – 305 .

Bermeo Nancy . 2009 . “ Poverty Inequality and Democracy (II): Does Electoral Democracy Boost Economic Equality? ” Journal of Democracy 20 ( 4 ): 21 – 35 .

Birdsall Nancy . 1999 . “ Education: The People's Asset .” Center on Social and Economic Dynamics Working Paper 5. Accessed August 13, 2020. https://www.researchgate.net/publication/5059764_Education_The_People's_Asset .

Birdsall Nancy , Londoño Juan Luis . 1997 . “ Asset Inequality Matters: An Assessment of the World Bank's Approach to Poverty Reduction .” The American Economic Review 87 ( 2 ): 32 – 37 .

Blotevogel Robert , Imamoglu Eslem , Moriyama Kenji , Sarr Babacar . 2020 . “ Measuring Income Inequality and Implications for Economic Transmission Channels .” IMF Working Paper WP/20/164 . Washington, DC : International Monetary Fund .

Boix Carles . 2003 . Democracy and Redistribution . Cambridge : Cambridge University Press .

Boix Carles , Stokes Susan C. . 2003 . “ Endogenous Democratization .” World Politics 55 ( 4 ): 517 – 49 .

Bollen Kenneth A. , Jackman Robert W. . 1985 . “ Political Democracy and the Size Distribution of Income .” American Sociological Review 50 ( 4 ): 438 – 57 .

Bosmans Kristof , Decanq Koen , Decoster André . 2014 . “ The Relativity of Decreasing Inequality between Countries .” Economica 81 ( 322 ): 276 – 92 .

Bourguignon Francois . 2015 . “ Revisiting the Debate on Inequality and Economic Development .” Revue d'économie politique 5 : 633 – 63 .

Buchmann Claudia , Hannum Emily . 2001 . “ Education and Stratification in Developing Countries: A Review of Theories and Research .” Annual Review of Sociology 27 ( 1 ): 77 – 102 .

Cancela Joao , Geys Benny . 2016 . “ Explaining Voter Turnout: A Meta-Analysis of National and Subnational Elections .” Electoral Studies 42 : 264 – 75 .

Castelló-Climent Amparo. 2010 . “ Inequality and Growth in Advanced Economies: An Empirical Investigation .” The Journal of Economic Inequality 8 : 293 – 321 .

Castells-Quintana David , Royuela Vicente , Thiel Fabian . 2019 . “ Inequality and Sustainable Development: Insights from an Analysis of the Human Development Index .” Sustainable Development 27 ( 3 ): 448 – 60 .

Checchi Daniele 2003 . “ Inequality in Incomes and Access to Education: A Cross-Country Analysis (1960–95) .” Labour 17 ( 2 ): 153 – 201 .

Chong Alberto , Gradstein Mark . 2007 . “ Inequality and Institutions .” Review of Economics and Statistics 89 ( 3 ): 454 – 65 .

Chong Alberto , Gradstein Mark . 2019 . “ Institutional Persistence, Income Inequality, and Individual Attitudes .” The Journal of Economic Inequality 17 ( 3 ): 401 – 13 .

Cingano Federico . 2014 . “ Trends in Income Inequality and Its Impact on Economic Growth .” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers 163 . Paris : OECD Publishing .

Clarke George R.G. 1995 . “ More Evidence on Income Distribution and Growth .” Journal of Development Economics 47 ( 2 ): 403 – 27 .

Dabla-Norris Era , Kochhar Kalpana , Suphaphiphat Nujin , Ricka Frantisek , Tsounta Evridiki . 2015 . “ Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality: A Global Perspective .” IMF Discussion Note SDN/15/13 . Washington, DC : International Monetary Fund .

De La Croix David , Doepke Matthias . 2003 . “ Inequality and Growth: Why Differential Fertility Matters .” American Economic Review 93 ( 4 ): 1091 – 113 .

Deaton Angus 2003 . “ Health, Inequality, and Economic Development .” Journal of Economic Literature 41 ( 1 ): 113 – 58 .

Deininger Klaus , Olinto Pedro . 2000 . “ Asset Distribution, Inequality, and Growth .” Policy Research Working Paper 2375 . Washington, DC : The World Bank .

Deininger Klaus , Squire Lyn . 1996 . “ A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality .” The World Bank Economic Review 10 ( 3 ): 565 – 91 .

Deininger Klaus , Squire Lyn . 1998 . “ New Ways of Looking at Old Issues: Inequality and Growth .” Journal of Development Economics 57 ( 2 ): 259 – 87 .

Dorsch Michael T. , Maarek Paul . 2020 . “ Economic Downturns, Inequality, and Democratic Improvements .” European Journal of Political Economy 62 ( C ): 1 – 21 .

Easterly William . 2007 . “ Inequality Does Cause Underdevelopment: Insights from a New Instrument .” Journal of Development Economics 84 ( 2 ): 755 – 76 .

Ehrhart Christophe . 2009 . “ The Effects of Inequality on Growth: A Survey of the Theoretical and Empirical Literature .” ECINEQ Working Paper Series 2009-107. ECINEQ - Society for the Study of Economic Inequality. Accessed November 16, 2020. http://www.ecineq.org/milano/WP/ECINEQ2009-107.pdf .

El-Shagi Makram , Shao Liang . 2019 . “ The Impact of Inequality and Redistribution on Growth .” Review of Income and Wealth 65 ( 2 ): 239 – 63 .

Esposito Lucio , Villaseñor Adrián . 2018 . “ Wealth Inequality, Educational Environment and School Enrolment: Evidence from Mexico .” The Journal of Development Studies 54 ( 11 ): 2095 – 118 .

Ferreira Francisco H.G. , Lakner Christoph , Lugo Maria Ana , Özler Berk . 2018 . “ Inequality of Opportunity and Economic Growth: How Much Can Cross-Country Regressions Really Tell Us? ” Review of Income and Wealth 64 ( 4 ): 800 – 27 .

Ferreira Francisco H.G. , Lustig Nora , Teles Daniel . 2015 . “ Appraising Cross-National Income Inequality Databases: An Introduction .” The Journal of Economic Inequality 13 : 497 – 526 .

Fields Gary . 1989 . “ A Compendium of Data on Inequality and Poverty for the Developing World .” Unpublished manuscript, Cornell University .

Flug Karnit , Spilimbergo Antonio , Wachtenheim Erik . 1998 . “ Investment in Education: Do Economic Volatility and Credit Constraints Matter? ” Journal of Development Economics 55 ( 2 ): 465 – 81 .

Forbes Kristin J. 2000 . “ A Reassessment of the Relationship between Inequality and Growth .” American Economic Review 90 ( 4 ): 869 – 87 .

Fukuyama Francis . 2011 . “ Poverty, Inequality, and Democracy: Dealing with Inequality .” Journal of Democracy 22 ( 3 ): 79 – 89 .

Galor Oded , Zeira Joseph . 1993 . “ Income Distribution and Macroeconomics .” The Review of Economic Studies 60 ( 1 ): 35 – 52 .

Galor Oded , Moav Omer . 2004 . “ From Physical to Human Capital Accumulation: Inequality and the Process of Development .” Review of Economic Studies 71 ( 4 ): 1001 – 26 .

García-Peñalosa Cecilia . 1995 . “ The Paradox of Education or the Good Side of Inequality .” Oxford Economic Papers 47 ( 2 ): 265 – 85 .

Glaeser Edward , Scheinkman Jose , Shleifer Andrei . 2003 . “ The Injustice of Inequality .” Journal of Monetary Economics 50 ( 1 ): 199 – 222 .

Graham Carol . 2014 . “ Concluding Remarks. How Inequality Matters to Well-Being .” In Happiness and Economic Growth: Lessons from Developing Countries , edited by Clark Andrew E. , Senik Claudia , 249 – 66 . Oxford : Oxford University Press .

Gründler Klaus , Scheuermeyer Philipp . 2018 . “ Growth Effects of Inequality and Redistribution: What Are the Transmission Channels? ” Journal of Macroeconomics 55 : 293 – 313 .

Gutiérrez Catalina , Tanaka Ryuichi . 2009 . “ Inequality and Education Decisions in Developing Countries .” The Journal of Economic Inequality 7 : 55 – 81 .

Haggard Stephan , Kaufman Robert R. . 2012 . “ Inequality and Regime Change: Democratic Transitions and the Stability of Democratic Rule .” American Political Science Review 106 ( 3 ): 495 – 516 .

Halter Daniel , Oechslin Manuel , Zweimüller Josef . 2014 . “ Inequality and Growth: The Neglected Time Dimension .” Journal of Economic Growth 19 ( 1 ): 81 – 104 .

Houle Christian 2009 . “ Inequality and Democracy: Why Inequality Harms Consolidation But Does Not Affect Democratization .” World Politics 61 ( 4 ): 589 – 622 .

Houle Christian . 2015 . “ Does Inequality Harm Economic Development and Democracy?: Accounting for Missing Values, Noncomparable Observations, and Endogeneity .” In The Oxford Handbook of the Politics of Development , edited by Lancaster Carol , Walle Nicolas Van de , 140 – 61 . New York : Oxford University Press .

Houle Christian . 2018 . “ Does Economic Inequality Breed Political Inequality? ” Democratization 25 ( 8 ): 1500 – 18 .

Islam Md. Rabiuk , McGillivray Mark . 2020 . “ Wealth Inequality, Governance and Economic Growth .” Economic Modelling 88 ( C ): 1 – 13 .

Iyigun Murat F. , Owen Ann L. . 2004 . “ Income Inequality, Financial Development, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations .” The Economic Journal 114 ( 495 ): 352 – 76 .

Jain Shail . 1975 . The Size Distribution of Income: A Compilation of Data . Washington, DC : World Bank .

Jäntti Markus , Pirtillä Jukka , Rönkkö Risto . 2020 . “ Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth Revisited: Comment on ‘Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth: New Evidence’ .” WIDER Working Paper 2020/117 . Helsinki : UNU-WIDER .

Jenkins Stephen P. 2015 . “ World Income Inequality Databases: An Assessment of WIID and SWIID .” The Journal of Economic Inequality 13 : 629 – 71 .

Jong-sung You , Khagram Sanjeev . 2005 . “ A Comparative Study of Inequality and Corruption .” American Sociological Review 70 ( 1 ): 136 – 57 .

Kabeer Naila 2015 . “ Gender, Poverty and Inequality: A Brief History of Feminist Contributions in the Field of International Development .” Gender & Development 23 ( 2 ): 189 – 205 .

Kaldor Nicholas . 1956 . “ Theories of Distribution .” The Review of Economic Studies 23 ( 2 ): 83 – 100 .

Karl Terry Lynn . 2000 . “ Economic Inequality and Democracy Instability .” Journal of Democracy 11 ( 1 ): 149 – 56 .

Keefer Philip , Knack Stephen . 2002 . “ Polarization, Politics and Property Rights: Links between Inequality and Growth .” Public Choice 111 : 127 – 54 .

Knack Stephen , Keefer Philip . 1997 . “ Does Inequality Harm Growth Only in Democracies? A Replication and Extension .” American Journal of Political Science 41 ( 1 ): 323 – 32 .

Knowles Stephen . 2005 . “ Inequality and Economic Growth: The Empirical Relationship Reconsidered in the Light of Comparable Data .” Journal of Development Studies 41 ( 1 ): 135 – 59 .

Kotschy Rainer , Sunde Uwe . 2017 . “ Democracy, Inequality, and Institutional Quality .” European Economic Review 91 ( C ): 209 – 28 .

Krieckhaus Jonathan , Son Byunghwan , Bellinger Nisha Mukherjee , Wells Jason M. . 2014 . “ Economic Inequality and Democratic Support .” The Journal of Politics 76 ( 1 ): 139 – 51 .

Kuznets Simon . 1955 . “ Economic Growth and Income Inequality .” The American Economic Review 45 ( 1 ): 1 – 28 .

La Ferrara Eliana . 2002 . “ Inequality and Group Participation: Theory and Evidence from Rural Tanzania .” Journal of Public Economics 85 ( 2 ): 235 – 73 .

Lecaillon Jacques , Paukert Felix , Morrison Christian , Germadis Dimitri . 1984 . Income Distribution and Economic Development: An Analytical Survey . Geneva : International Labour Office .

Leigh Andrew , Christopher Jencks , Smeeding Timothy M. . 2011 . “ Health and Economic Inequality .” In The Oxford Handbook of Economic Inequality , edited by Nolan Brian , Salverda Wiemer , Smeeding Timothy M. , 384 – 405 . New York : Oxford University Press .

Lengfelder Christina 2019 . “ Exploring Dynamics of Inequality in Human Development .” 2019 UNDP Human Development Report, Background Paper NO. 3-2019. United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). Accessed June 6, 2020. http://hdr.undp.org/en/content/exploring-dynamics-inequality-human-development .

Li Hongyi , Zou Heng-fu . 1998 . “ Income Inequality Is Not Harmful for Growth: Theory and Evidence .” Review of Development Economics 2 ( 3 ): 318 – 34 .

Lynch John , Smith George Davey , Harper Sam , Hillemeier Marianne , Ross Nancy , Kaplan George A. , Wolfson Michael . 2004 . “ Is Income Inequality a Determinant of Population Health? Part 1. A Systematic Review .” The Milbank Quarterly 82 ( 1 ): 5 – 99 .

Madsen Jakob B. , Islam Md. Rabiuk , Doucouliagos Hristos . 2018 . “ Inequality, Financial Development and Economic Growth in the OECD, 1870–2011 .” European Economic Review 101 ( C ): 605 – 24 .

Maliniak Daniel , Powers Ryan , Walter Barbara F. . 2013 . “ The Gender Citation Gap in International Relations .” International Organization 67 ( 4 ): 889 – 922 .

Marrero Gustavo A. , Rodríguez Juan G. . 2013 . “ Inequality of Opportunity and Growth .” Journal of Development Economics 104 ( C ): 107 – 22 .

Mayer Susan E. 2001 . “ How Did the Increase in Economic Inequality between 1970 and 1990 Affect Children's Educational Attainment? ” American Journal of Sociology 107 ( 1 ): 1 – 32 .

Mellor Jennifer M. , Milyo Jeffrey . 2002 . “ Income Inequality and Health Status in the United States .” The Journal of Human Resources 37 ( 3 ): 510 – 39 .

Morelli Salvatore , Atkinson Anthony B. . 2015 . “ Inequality and Crises Revisited .” Economia Politica 32 : 31 – 51 .

Murphy Kevin M. , Shleifer Andrei , Vishny Robert . 1989 . “ Income Distribution, Market Size and Industrialization .” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 ( 3 ): 537 – 64 .

Neves Pedro Cunha , Silva Sandra Maria Tavares . 2014 . “ Inequality and Growth; Uncovering the Main Conclusions from the Empirics .” The Journal of Development Studies 50 ( 1 ): 1 – 21 .

Niño-Zarazúa Miguel , Roope Lawrence , Tarp Finn . 2017 . “ Global Inequality: Relatively Lower, Absolutely Higher .” Review of Income and Wealth 63 ( 4 ): 661 – 84 .

Nolan Brian , Valenzuela Luis . 2019 . “ Inequality and Its Discontents .” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 35 ( 3 ): 396 – 430 .

O'Donnell Owen , van Doorslaer Eddy , van Ourti Tom . 2015 . “ Health and Inequality .” In Handbook of Income Distribution , Volume 2B, edited by Atkinson Anthony B. , Francois Bourguignon , 1419 – 533 . Amsterdam : Elsevier .

Østby Gudrun . 2013 . “ Inequality and Political Violence: A Review of the Literature .” International Area Studies Review 16 ( 2 ): 206 – 31 .

Ostry Jonathan D. , Berg Andrew , Tsangarides Charalambos G. . 2014 . “ Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth .” IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/14/02 . Washington, DC : International Monetary Fund .

Panizza Ugo . 2002 . “ Income Inequality and Economic Growth: Evidence from American Data .” Journal of Economic Growth 7 : 25 – 41 .

Partridge Mark D. 1997 . “ Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? Comment .” The American Economic Review 87 ( 5 ): 1019 – 32 .

Paukert Felix . 1973 . “ Income Distribution at Different Levels of Development: A Survey of the Evidence .” International Labour Review 108 : 97 – 125 .

Perotti Roberto . 1996 . “ Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data Say .” Journal of Economic Growth 1 : 149 – 87 .

Persson Torsten , Tabellini Guido . 1994 . “ Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? ” The American Economic Review 84 ( 3 ): 600 – 21 .

Pickett Kate E. , Wilkinson Richard G. . 2015 . “ Income Inequality and Health: A Causal Review .” Social Science & Medicine 128 : 316 – 26 .

Ravallion Martin 2001 . “ Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages .” World Development 29 ( 11 ): 1803 – 15 .

Ravallion Martin . 2012 . “ Why Don't We See Poverty Convergence? ” American Economic Review 102 ( 1 ): 504 – 23 .

Roodman David . 2009 . “ A Note on the Theme of Too Many Instruments .” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 71 ( 1 ): 135 – 58 .

Rothstein Bo , Uslaner Eric M. . 2005 . “ All for All: Equality, Corruption, and Social Trust .” World Politics 58 ( 1 ): 41 – 72 .

Rowlingson Karen 2011 . “ Does Income Inequality Cause Health and Social Problems? ” Joseph Rowntree Foundation, York. Accessed October 4, 2021. https://www.jrf.org.uk/file/41359/download?token=VV7qsS1J&filetype=full-report .

Sandmo Agnar . 2015 . “ The Principal Problem in Political Economy: Income Distribution in the History of Economic Thought .” In Handbook of Income Distribution , Volume 2, edited by Atkinson Anthony B. , Bourguignon Francois , 3 – 65 . Amsterdam : Elsevier .

Savoia Antonio , Easaw Joshy , McKay Andrew . 2010 . “ Inequality, Democracy, and Institutions: A Critical Review of Recent Research .” World Development 38 ( 2 ): 142 – 54 .

Schäfer Armin , Schwander Hanna . 2019 . “ ‘Don't Play If You Can't Win’: Does Economic Inequality Undermine Political Equality .” European Political Science Review 11 ( 3 ): 395 – 413 .

Scheve Kenneth , Stasavage David . 2017 . “ Wealth Inequality and Democracy .” Annual Review of Political Science 20 : 451 – 68 .

Scholl Nathalie , Klasen Stephan . 2019 . “ Re-Estimating the Relationship between Inequality and Growth .” Oxford Economic Papers 71 ( 4 ): 824 – 47 .

Solt Frederick . 2008 . “ Economic Inequality and Democratic Political Engagement .” American Journal of Political Science 52 ( 1 ): 48 – 60 .

Solt Frederick . 2009 . “ Standardizing the World Income Inequality Database .” Social Science Quarterly 90 ( 2 ): 231 – 42 .

Solt Frederick . 2020 . “ Measuring Income Inequality across Countries and over Time: The Standardized World Income Inequality Database .” Social Science Quarterly 101 ( 3 ): 1183 – 99 .

Stewart Frances . 2005 . “ Horizontal Inequalities: A Neglected Dimension of Development .” In Wider Perspectives on Global Development , edited by Shorrocks Anthony F. , 101 – 35 . London : Palgrave Macmillan .

Stewart Frances . 2016 . “ Changing Perspectives on Inequality and Development .” Studies in Comparative International Development 51 : 60 – 80 .

Stockemer Daniel , Scruggs Lyle . 2012 . “ Income Inequality, Development and Electoral Turnout—New Evidence on a Burgeoning Debate .” Electoral Studies 31 ( 4 ): 764 – 73 .

Subramanian S.V. , Kawachi Ichiro . 2004 . “ Income Inequality and Health: What Have We Learned So Far? ” Epidemiologic Reviews 26 ( 1 ): 78 – 91 .

Sylwester Kevin 2000 . “ Income Inequality, Education Expenditures, and Growth .” Journal of Development Economics 63 ( 2 ): 379 – 98 .

Tanaka Ryuichi 2003 . “ Inequality as a Determinant of Child Labor .” Economics Letters 80 ( 1 ): 93 – 97 .

Thorbecke Erik 2016 . “ Inequality and the Trade-Off between Efficiency and Equity .” Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 17 ( 3 ): 460 – 64 .

Thorbecke Erik , Charumilind Chutatong . 2002 . “ Economic Inequality and Its Socioeconomic Impact .” World Development 30 ( 9 ): 1477 – 95 .

Uslaner Eric M. 2017 . “ Political Trust, Corruption, and Inequality .” In Handbook on Political Trust , edited by Zmerli Sonja , van der Meer Tom W.G. , 302 – 15 . Chelton : Edward Elgar Publishing .

Voitchovsky Sarah 2005 . “ Does the Profile of Income Inequality Matter for Economic Growth? Distinguishing between the Effects of Inequality in Different Parts of the Income Distribution .” Journal of Economic Growth 10 : 273 – 96 .

Voitchovsky Sarah . 2011 . “ Inequality and Economic Growth .” In The Oxford Handbook of Economic Inequality , edited by Nolan Brian , Salverda Wiemer , Smeeding Timothy M. , 549 – 74 . New York : Oxford University Press .

Wagstaff Adam , van Doorslaer Eddy . 2000 . “ Income Inequality and Health: What Does the Literature Tell Us? ” Annual Review of Public Health 21 : 543 – 67 .

Walraevens Benoît . 2021 . “ Adam Smith's View of Economic Inequality .” Cambridge Journal of Economics 45 ( 1 ): 209 – 24 .

WID.world . 2017 . “ World Inequality Database .” Accessed January 26, 2021. https://wid.world .

Wilkinson Richard G. , Pickett Kate E. . 2006 . “ Income Inequality and Population Health: A Review and Explanation of the Evidence .” Social Science & Medicine 62 ( 7 ): 1768 – 84 .

World Bank . 2006 . World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development . Washington, DC : World Bank .

Zweimüller Josef . 2000 . “ Schumpeterian Entrepreneurs Meet Engel's Law: The Impact of Inequality on Innovation-Driven Growth .” Journal of Economic Growth 5 : 185 – 206 .

Month: Total Views:
December 2021 138
January 2022 295
February 2022 368
March 2022 525
April 2022 551
May 2022 465
June 2022 343
July 2022 251
August 2022 200
September 2022 346
October 2022 575
November 2022 615
December 2022 742
January 2023 538
February 2023 498
March 2023 704
April 2023 766
May 2023 800
June 2023 534
July 2023 317
August 2023 452
September 2023 553
October 2023 644
November 2023 800
December 2023 688
January 2024 713
February 2024 703
March 2024 978
April 2024 716
May 2024 839
June 2024 504
July 2024 578
August 2024 918
September 2024 445

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Recommend to your Library

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1468-2486
  • Print ISSN 1521-9488
  • Copyright © 2024 International Studies Association
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Institutional account management
  • Rights and permissions
  • Get help with access
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

Rising inequality affecting more than two-thirds of the globe, but it’s not inevitable: new UN report

Students attend class at Zanaki primary school in Dar es Salaam, Tanzania.

Facebook Twitter Print Email

Inequality is growing for more than 70 per cent of the global population, exacerbating the risks of divisions and hampering economic and social development. But the rise is far from inevitable and can be tackled at a national and international level, says a flagship study released by the UN on Tuesday.

The World Social Report 2020, published by the UN Department of Economic and Social Affairs (DESA), shows that income inequality has increased in most developed countries, and some middle-income countries - including China, which has the world’s fastest growing economy.

The challenges are underscored by UN chief António Guterres in the foreword, in which he states that the world is confronting “the harsh realities of a deeply unequal global landscape”, in which economic woes, inequalities and job insecurity have led to mass protests in both developed and developing countries.

 “Income disparities and a lack of opportunities”, he writes, “are creating a vicious cycle of inequality, frustration and discontent across generations.”

‘The one per cent’ winners take (almost) all

The study shows that the richest one per cent of the population are the big winners in the changing global economy, increasing their share of income between 1990 and 2015, while at the other end of the scale, the bottom 40 per cent earned less than a quarter of income in all countries surveyed.

One of the consequences of inequality within societies, notes the report, is slower economic growth. In unequal societies, with wide disparities in areas such as health care and education, people are more likely to remain trapped in poverty, across several generations.

Between countries, the difference in average incomes is reducing, with China and other Asian nations driving growth in the global economy. Nevertheless, there are still stark differences between the richest and poorest countries and regions: the average income in North America, for example, is 16 times higher than that of people in Sub-Saharan Africa.

Four global forces affecting inequality

The Delmas 32 neighbourhood in the Haitian capital, Port-au-Prince is one of the poorest in the Caribbean country.

The report looks at the impact that four powerful global forces, or megatrends, are having on inequality around the world: technological innovation, climate change, urbanization and international migration.

Whilst technological innovation can support economic growth, offering new possibilities in fields such as health care, education, communication and productivity, there is also evidence to show that it can lead to increased wage inequality, and displace workers.

Rapid advances in areas such as biology and genetics, as well as robotics and artificial intelligence, are transforming societies at pace. New technology has the potential to eliminate entire categories of jobs but, equally, may generate entirely new jobs and innovations.

For now, however, highly skilled workers are reaping the benefits of the so-called “fourth industrial revolution”, whilst low-skilled and middle-skilled workers engaged in routine manual and cognitive tasks, are seeing their opportunities shrink.

Opportunities in a crisis

UN Development Programme (UNDP) and UN Climate Change (UNFCCC) launch a comprehensive report on how the world can take swift and meaningful action to slow down climate change.

As the UN’s 2020 report on the global economy showed last Thursday, the climate crisis is having a negative impact on quality of life, and vulnerable populations are bearing the brunt of environmental degradation and extreme weather events. Climate change, according to the World Social Report, is making the world’s poorest countries even poorer, and could reverse progress made in reducing inequality among countries.

If action to tackle the climate crisis progresses as hoped, there will be job losses in carbon-intensive sectors, such as the coal industry, but the “greening” of the global economy could result in overall net employment gains, with the creation of many new jobs worldwide.

For the first time in history, more people live in urban than rural areas, a trend that is expected to continue over the coming years. Although cities drive economic growth, they are more unequal than rural areas, with the extremely wealthy living alongside the very poor.

The scale of inequality varies widely from city to city, even within a single country: as they grow and develop, some cities have become more unequal whilst, in others, inequality has declined.

Migration a ‘powerful symbol of global inequality’

The fourth megatrend, international migration, is described as both a “powerful symbol of global inequality”, and “a force for equality under the right conditions”.

Migration within countries, notes the report, tends to increase once countries begin to develop and industrialize, and more inhabitants of middle-income countries than low-income countries migrate abroad.

International migration is seen, generally, as benefiting both migrants, their countries of origin (as money is sent home) and their host countries.

In some cases, where migrants compete for low-skilled work, wages may be pushed down, increasing inequality but, if they offer skills that are in short supply, or take on work that others are not willing to do, they can have a positive effect on unemployment.

Harness the megatrends for a better world

World Social Report

Despite a clear widening of the gap between the haves and have-nots worldwide, the report points out that this situation can be reversed. Although the megatrends have the potential to continue divisions in society, they can also, as the Secretary-General says in his foreword, “be harnessed for a more equitable and sustainable world”. Both national governments and international organizations have a role to play in levelling the playing field and creating a fairer world for all.

Reducing inequality should, says the report, play a central role in policy-making. This means ensuring that the potential of new technology is used to reduce poverty and create jobs; that vulnerable people grow more resilient to the effects of climate change; cities are more inclusive; and migration takes place in a safe, orderly and regular manner.

Three strategies for making countries more egalitarian are suggested in the report: the promotion of equal access to opportunities (through, for example, universal access to education); fiscal policies that include measures for social policies, such as unemployment and disability benefits; and legislation that tackles prejudice and discrimination, whilst promoting greater participation of disadvantaged groups.

While action at a national level is crucial, the report declares that “concerted, coordinated and multilateral action” is needed to tackle major challenges affecting inequality within and among countries.

The report’s authors conclude that, given the importance of international cooperation, multilateral institutions such as the UN should be strengthened and action to create a fairer world must be urgently accelerated.

The UN’s 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development , which provides the blueprint for a better future for people and the planet, recognizes that major challenges require internationally coordinated solutions, and contains concrete and specific targets to reduce inequality, based on income.

  • World Social Report
  • Yale University
  • About Yale Insights
  • Privacy Policy
  • Accessibility

The Roots of Economic Inequality

A new study shows that deeply ingrained social behaviors play a role in perpetuating economic inequality. Yale SOM’s Michael Kraus, one of the authors of the study, says we all need to mind the widening gap between rich and poor.

Workers and customers in a nail salon

Photo: Joanne Kim

  • Michael W. Kraus Associate Professor of Organizational Behavior

The United States is divided by wealth and social class, and the gap is widening.

In 1980, according to the World Inequality Report, the richest 10% of the population held just under 35% of national income; by 2016, that share had risen to around 47%. As wealth disparities have widened, so have differences in outcomes. The rich now have a hugely better chance at educational attainment, good health, and even longer life expectancy than the poor.

Economic inequality is rising despite the fact that most people agree things should be shared more equally, says Michael Kraus, assistant professor of organizational behavior at the Yale School of Management. So why is it so hard to change the systems that perpetuate the problem?

Kraus, UC Irvine’s Paul Piff and UC Berkeley’s Dacher Keltner investigated this question through the lens of psychology. In a paper in Advances in Experimental Social Psychology , the authors put forth a conceptual model, drawing on existing research, to show how individuals maintain inequality through their actions and beliefs. The authors look at five domains of social life—structural barriers, social class signaling, ideologies of merit, moral-relational tendencies, and intergroup processes—and detail how they perpetuate class divisions in everyday life.

Read the study: “Unpacking the Inequality Paradox: The Psychological Roots of Inequality and Social Class ”

The study as a whole, Kraus says, shows that even “mundane, everyday beliefs and behaviors are contributing to rising inequality.” What we wear and how we speak, for example, can determine whether an employer hires us or not, whether we succeed in networking or not. And such class signaling happens fast; in one study the authors cite, and which Kraus conducted, participants from across the U.S. successfully guessed a speaker’s social class after hearing them speak just seven words, out of context . “And that’s a problem for a job interview,” says Kraus. “It might be a problem for an admissions interview for college, and it certainly could create socialization challenges if you go to college and you’re speaking a different way than some of the other students.”

How we think about merit and hard work hinders the advancement of working class individuals and is highly advantageous to upper class ones, the authors write. We’re quite blind to just how unequal our society is, and “a lot of that thinking is driven by broader beliefs that life has to be fair and it’s getting more fair,” says Kraus. But that is simply not the case, as economic indicators show. Upper-class individuals are more likely to believe wealth is primarily a product of hard work and effort, which generally isn’t the case; inherited wealth has an immense impact on social class. But this idea—the deeply held belief that we live in a meritocracy—means that people born to lower-class families are blamed for their poverty and face an additional headwind when trying to catch up.

While the authors look at the psychological roots of inequality, “one of the dangers here,” says Kraus, “is to say that inequality exists in people’s minds.” There are objective, structural barriers that perpetuate inequality, and reinforce our flawed thinking about it, the authors write. Universities are a good example. At elite institutions, poor students are usually a minority; surrounded by classmates—and taught by professors—from middle- and upper-class backgrounds, their academic performance is impeded by anxiety about whether they belong and whether failure will confirm stereotypes about their class. One study suggested that this anxiety is well founded: evaluators found more mistakes in work from students that they believed were lower in social class. Meanwhile, the same structures that disadvantage the poor afford upper-class individuals a leg up. The wealthy benefit and then award the university or other institutions with more resources, continuing a cycle that rewards the wealthy.

The study’s findings aren’t easy to swallow, says Kraus. “Maybe we’re a little too optimistic about how things will get better automatically. Maybe we need to acknowledge our collective part in perpetuating systems of inequality.”

But that’s why more psychologists should be studying inequality. “It’s powerful to get psychologists to talk about and underscore all the ways in which everyday interactions and psychological processes that people engage in can be in the service of big economic patterns,” says Kraus. “We are really motivated to keep things the way they are, and to change, we need to start with an acknowledgement that things are off.”

More research can help. For instance, studies that combat ideologies of merit and that raise awareness of the racial patterns of economic inequality help address the psychological roots of inequality by changing people’s thinking on the topic.

But real change will require policy solutions. A more equal society “relies on us creating structures and bureaucracy that allow us to overcome our biases,” Kraus says. He and his colleagues call on the U.S. to adopt “large-scale government programs” and policy changes to reduce structural barriers to equality, including better access to education, a higher minimum wage, and a universal basic income.

While a challenging road lies ahead, Kraus considers the study a good starting point. “We have to acknowledge the real work necessary to create meaningful change,” he says. That starts with understanding just how pervasive inequality is.

Related: Watch a Yale Insights interview with Michael Kraus on how Americans misperceive progress toward racial economic equality.

  • Diversity and Inclusion

Numbers, Facts and Trends Shaping Your World

Read our research on:

Full Topic List

Regions & Countries

  • Publications
  • Our Methods
  • Short Reads
  • Tools & Resources

Read Our Research On:

6 facts about economic inequality in the U.S.

Houses in Naples, Florida. (Jeffrey Greenberg/Education Images/Universal Images Group via Getty Images)

Rising economic inequality in the United States has become a central issue in the race for the Democratic presidential nomination, and discussions about policy interventions that might help address it are likely to remain at the forefront in the 2020 general election .

As these debates continue, here are some basic facts about how economic inequality has changed over time and how the U.S. compares globally.

How we did this

For this analysis, we gathered data from the U.S. Census Bureau, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development and the World Bank . We also used previously published data points from Pew Research Center surveys and analyses of outside data.

The highest-earning 20% of families made more than half of all U.S. income in 2018

Over the past 50 years, the highest-earning 20% of U.S. households have steadily brought in a larger share of the country’s total income. In 2018, households in the top fifth of earners (with incomes of $130,001 or more that year) brought in 52% of all U.S. income, more than the lower four-fifths combined, according to Census Bureau data.

In 1968, by comparison, the top-earning 20% of households brought in 43% of the nation’s income, while those in the lower four income quintiles accounted for 56%.

U.S. has highest level of income inequality among G7 countries

Among the top 5% of households – those with incomes of at least $248,729 in 2018 – their share of all U.S. income rose from 16% in 1968 to 23% in 2018.

Income inequality in the U.S. is the highest of all the G7 nations , according to data from the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development . To compare income inequality across countries, the OECD uses the Gini coefficient , a commonly used measure ranging from 0, or perfect equality, to 1, or complete inequality. In 2017, the U.S. had a Gini coefficient of 0.434. In the other G7 nations, the Gini ranged from 0.326 in France to 0.392 in the UK.

Globally, the Gini ranges from lows of about 0.25 in some Eastern European countries to highs of 0.5 to 0.6 in countries in southern Africa, according to World Bank estimates .

In the U.S., black-white income gap has held steady since 1970

The black-white income gap in the U.S. has persisted over time. The difference in median household incomes between white and black Americans has grown from about $23,800 in 1970 to roughly $33,000 in 2018 (as measured in 2018 dollars). Median black household income was 61% of median white household income in 2018, up modestly from 56% in 1970 – but down slightly from 63% in 2007, before the Great Recession , according to Current Population Survey data.

Overall, 61% of Americans say there is too much economic inequality in the country today, but views differ by political party and household income level. Among Republicans and those who lean toward the GOP, 41% say there is too much inequality in the U.S., compared with 78% of Democrats and Democratic leaners, a Pew Research Center survey conducted in September 2019 found.

Democrats are nearly twice as likely as Republicans to say there's too much economic inequality

Across income groups, U.S. adults are about equally likely to say there is too much economic inequality. But upper- (27%) and middle-income Americans (26%) are more likely than those with lower incomes (17%) to say that there is about the right amount of economic inequality.

These views also vary by income within the two party coalitions. Lower-income Republicans are more likely than upper-income ones to say there’s too much inequality in the country today (48% vs. 34%). Among Democrats, the reverse is true: 93% at upper-income levels say there is too much inequality, compared with 65% of lower-income Democrats.

Since 1981, the incomes of the top 5% of earners have increased faster than the incomes of other families

The wealth gap between America’s richest and poorer families more than doubled from 1989 to 2016, according to a recent analysis by the Center. Another way of measuring inequality is to look at household wealth, also known as net worth, or the value of assets owned by a family, such as a home or a savings account, minus outstanding debt, such as a mortgage or student loan.

In 1989, the richest 5% of families had 114 times as much wealth as families in the second quintile (one tier above the lowest), at the median $2.3 million compared with $20,300. By 2016, the top 5% held 248 times as much wealth at the median. (The median wealth of the poorest 20% is either zero or negative in most years we examined.)

The richest families are also the only ones whose wealth increased in the years after the start of the Great Recession. From 2007 to 2016, the median net worth of the top 20% increased 13%, to $1.2 million. For the top 5%, it increased by 4%, to $4.8 million. In contrast, the median net worth of families in lower tiers of wealth decreased by at least 20%. Families in the second-lowest fifth experienced a 39% loss (from $32,100 in 2007 to $19,500 in 2016).

Middle-class incomes have grown at a slower rate than upper-tier incomes over the past five decades, the same analysis found . From 1970 to 2018, the median middle-class income increased from $58,100 to $86,600, a gain of 49%. By comparison, the median income for upper-tier households grew 64% over that time, from $126,100 to $207,400.

The share of American adults who live in middle-income households has decreased from 61% in 1971 to 51% in 2019. During this time, the share of adults in the upper-income tier increased from 14% to 20%, and the share in the lower-income tier increased from 25% to 29%.

The gaps in income between upper-income and middle- and lower-income households are rising, and the share held by middle-income households is falling

  • Economic Inequality
  • Economy & Work
  • Income & Wages
  • Income, Wealth & Poverty
  • Personal Finances

Download Katherine Schaeffer's photo

Katherine Schaeffer is a research analyst at Pew Research Center .

Income inequality is greater among Chinese Americans than any other Asian origin group in the U.S.

1 in 10: redefining the asian american dream (short film), the hardships and dreams of asian americans living in poverty, a booming u.s. stock market doesn’t benefit all racial and ethnic groups equally, black americans’ views on success in the u.s., most popular.

901 E St. NW, Suite 300 Washington, DC 20004 USA (+1) 202-419-4300 | Main (+1) 202-857-8562 | Fax (+1) 202-419-4372 |  Media Inquiries

Research Topics

  • Email Newsletters

ABOUT PEW RESEARCH CENTER  Pew Research Center is a nonpartisan, nonadvocacy fact tank that informs the public about the issues, attitudes and trends shaping the world. It does not take policy positions. The Center conducts public opinion polling, demographic research, computational social science research and other data-driven research. Pew Research Center is a subsidiary of The Pew Charitable Trusts , its primary funder.

© 2024 Pew Research Center

Oxford Martin School logo

The history of global economic inequality

The inequality in people’s living conditions across the world is extremely large. how did the world become so unequal, and what can we expect for the future.

This article was originally published in 2017. The data shown and discussed in the text are therefore not always the latest estimates. For more up-to-date data, see our Data Explorers on Poverty and Inequality .

The inequality in people’s living conditions today is extremely large. The panel of charts below shows how large these differences are, and how the inequality in 12 important measures of living standards maps onto the economic inequality in the world.

What is most important for how healthy, wealthy, and educated you are is not who you are, but where you are. This was the point I made in another article . A person’s knowledge, skills, and how hard they work all matter for whether they are poor or not – but all these personal factors together matter less than the one factor that is entirely outside of a person’s control: whether they happen to be born into a large, productive economy or not.

How did we get here? How did the world become so unequal, and what can we expect for the future?

legacy-wordpress-upload

Global divergence followed by convergence

The chart shows estimates of the distribution of annual income among all world citizens over the last two centuries.

To make incomes comparable across countries and time, daily incomes are measured in international-$ — a hypothetical currency that would buy a comparable amount of goods and services that a U.S. dollar would buy in the United States in 2011 (for a more detailed explanation, see here ).

The distribution of incomes is shown at 3 points in time:

  • By 1800, few countries had achieved economic growth. The chart shows that most of the world lived in poverty with an income similar to today's poorest countries. At the beginning of the 19th century, the vast majority— roughly 80% —of the world lived in material conditions that we would refer to as extreme poverty today.
  • In 1975, 175 years later, the world had changed—it had become very unequal. The world income distribution was 'bimodal', with the two-humped shape of a camel: one hump below the international poverty line and a second hump at considerably higher incomes. The world had divided into a poor, developing world and a developed world more than 10-times richer.
  • Over the following 4 decades, the world income distribution has again changed dramatically. There has been a convergence in incomes: in many poorer countries, especially in South-East Asia, incomes have grown faster than in rich countries. While enormous income differences remain, the world can no longer be neatly divided into 'developed' and 'developing' countries. We have moved from a two-hump to a one-hump world. And at the same time, the distribution has also shifted to the right—the incomes of many of the world's poorest citizens have increased, and extreme poverty has fallen faster than ever before in human history.

We have visualized a similar dataset from the OECD here . 1

legacy-wordpress-upload

Global income inequality increased for two centuries and is now falling

This visualization shows the distribution of incomes between 1988 and 2011. The data was compiled by the economists Branko Milanovic and Christoph Lakner. 3

To see the change over time, select the years above the distribution.

The previous visualization, which showed the change from 1820 to the year 2015, is based on estimates of inflation-adjusted average incomes per country (GDP per capita) and a measure of income inequality within a country only. It gives us a rough idea of how the distribution of incomes changed, but it is not very detailed or precise. In contrast to this, the work by Branko Milanovic and Christoph Lakner is based on much more detailed household survey data. This data measures household income at each decile of the income distribution, and the two authors used this information to arrive at the global income distribution. The downside of this approach is that we can only go as far back in time as household surveys were conducted in many countries around the world.

The visualization shows the end of the long era in human history in which global inequality was increasing. Starting with industrialization in North-Western Europe, incomes in this part of the world started to increase while material prosperity in the rest of the world remained low. While some countries followed European industrialization – first Northern America, Oceania, and parts of South America and later Japan and East Asia – other countries in Asia and Africa remained poor. As a consequence of this, global inequality increased over a long period. Only in the period shown in this visualization did this change: with rapid growth in much of Asia and Latin America, the global distribution of incomes became less unequal. The incomes of the poorer half of the world population rose faster than the incomes of the richer half.

Global Income Distribution 1988 to 2011 3

If you want to use this visualization for a presentation or teaching purposes, download a zip folder with an image file for every year and an animated .gif here .

A look into the future of global inequality

This visualization shows how the global income distribution has changed over the decade up to 2013. Tomáš Hellebrandt and Paolo Mauro, the authors of the paper 4 from which this data is taken, confirm the finding that global inequality has declined but remains very high: the Gini coefficient of global inequality has declined from 68.7 to 64.9.

The visualizations above show the income distribution on a logarithmic x-axis. This chart, in contrast, plots incomes on a linear x-axis and thereby emphasizes how very high global inequality still is: The bulk of the world population lives on very low incomes, and the income distribution stretches out very far to the higher incomes at the right-hand side of the chart; incomes over 14,000 international-$ are cut off as they would make this chart with a linear x-axis unreadable.

A second positive global development shown in this chart is the rise of the global median income. In 2003 half of the world's population lived on less than 1,090 international-$ per year, and the other half lived on more than 1,090 international-$. This level of global median income has almost doubled over the last decade and was 2,010 international-$ in 2013.

Finally, the authors also dare to project what global inequality will look like in 2035. Assuming the growth rates shown in the insert in the top-right corner, the authors project global inequality to decline further and to reach a Gini of 61.3. At the same time, the incomes of the world's poorer half would continue to increase significantly, so that the global median income could again double and reach 4,000 international-$ in 2035.

If you are looking for a visualization of only the observed global income distribution in 2003 and 2013, you can find it here .

legacy-wordpress-upload

How global inequality has changed from 2003 to 2013

The following visualization offers an alternative view of the data by Hellebrandt and Mauro 4 shown in the chart before.

The chart shows the yearly disposable income for all world citizens in both 2003 and 2013. On the x-axis, you see the position of an individual in the global distribution of incomes. On the logarithmic y-axis, you see the annual disposable income at that position.

The increase in prosperity—and decrease in poverty—is substantial. The income cut-off of the poorest 10% has increased from 260 international-$ to 480 international-%, and the median income has almost doubled from 1,100 international-$ to 2,010. Global mean income in 2013 was 5,375 international-$. 5

At the same it is still the case, as emphasized before, that incomes are very low for most people in the world.

legacy-wordpress-upload

Global income inequality is very high and will likely stay high for a long time

The visualization presents the same data in the same way, except that the y-axis is now not logarithmic but linear. This perspective shows the still very high level of global inequality even more clearly.

The previous and the following visualization show how high global income inequality is. The cut-off to the richest 10% of the world in 2013 was 14,500 int-$; the cut-off for the poorest 10% was 480 int-$. The ratio is 30.2.

While global inequality is still very high, we live in a period of falling inequality. In 2003, this ratio was 37.6. The Gini coefficient has also fallen from 68.7 to 64.9.

Taking the historical experience as a guide for what is possible in the future, we have to conclude that global inequality will remain high for a long time. To understand this, we can ask how long it would take for those with incomes at the poorest 10% cutoff to achieve the current incomes of the richest 10% cutoff (14,500 international-$). This income level is roughly the level of GDP per capita above which the extreme poverty headcount gets close to 0% for most countries ( see here ).

Even under a very optimistic scenario, it will take several decades for the poorest regions to reach the income level of the global top 10%.

2% is roughly the growth rate that the richest countries of today experienced over the last decades ( see here ). We have seen that poorer countries can achieve faster growth, but we have not seen growth rates of more than 6% over a time frame as long as necessary to reach the level of the global 10% in such a short time. If the past is a good guide for the future, the world will likely be highly unequal for a long time.

legacy-wordpress-upload

How long does it take for incomes to grow from 480 int-$ to 14,500 int-$?

2% growth172.1 years
4% growth86.9 years
6% growth58.5 years
8% growth44.3 years
10% growth35.8 years

Inequality within countries and inequality between countries

Global inequality is driven by changes in both the inequality within countries, and the inequality between countries. This visualization shows how both of these changes determine the changing global inequality.

  • Inequality within countries followed a U-shape pattern over the 20th century.
  • Inequality between countries increased over 2 centuries and peaked in the 1980s, according to the data from Bourguignon and Morrison. Since then, inequality between countries has declined.

As is shown in this visualization, the inequality of income between different countries is much higher than the inequality within countries. The consequence of this is that the trend of global inequality is very much driven by what is happening to the inequality between countries.

I have taken the data for the visualization of the world income distribution in 1820, 1970, and 2000 from van Zanden, J.L., et al. (eds.) (2014), How Was Life?: Global Well-being since 1820, OECD Publishing. Online here . The plotted data is interpolated using a Cardinal spline.

The data is originally from the Clio-Infra database here .

The data are produced by Ola Rosling and published on the website of Gapminder.

You can explore the Gapminder visualization of the income distributions of all countries in their interactive tool here . Regarding the construction of the data, Hans and Ola Rosling note the following here : “This graph is constructed by combining data from multiple sources. In summary, we take the best available country estimates for the three indicators: GDP per capita, Population, and Gini coefficient (a measure of income inequality). With these numbers, we can approximate the number of people at different income levels in every country. We then combine all these approximations into a global pile using the method described below under The Adjusted Global Income Scale.”

The data was made available to Our World In Data by the two authors. The data up to 2008 is published with the main publication Milanovic and Lakner (2015) –Global Income Distribution. Available online at the World Bank: http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/abs/10.1596/1813-9450-6719 .

The data source is: Hellebrandt, Tomas and Mauro, Paolo (2015) – The Future of Worldwide Income Distribution (April 1, 2015). Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper No. 15-7. Available at SSRN or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2593894 .

We thank the authors for making the data available for this data visualization.

Note that global GDP per capita in 2013 was around 14,000 international-$ and substantially higher than mean disposable income from household-level surveys at 5,375 international-$.

We discuss the reasons for this discrepancy here . See also the Appendix of the original publication for a longer explanation.

Cite this work

Our articles and data visualizations rely on work from many different people and organizations. When citing this article, please also cite the underlying data sources. This article can be cited as:

BibTeX citation

Reuse this work freely

All visualizations, data, and code produced by Our World in Data are completely open access under the Creative Commons BY license . You have the permission to use, distribute, and reproduce these in any medium, provided the source and authors are credited.

The data produced by third parties and made available by Our World in Data is subject to the license terms from the original third-party authors. We will always indicate the original source of the data in our documentation, so you should always check the license of any such third-party data before use and redistribution.

All of our charts can be embedded in any site.

Our World in Data is free and accessible for everyone.

Help us do this work by making a donation.

Poverty Reduction: Concept, Approaches, and Case Studies

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online: 10 January 2020
  • Cite this living reference work entry

case study on economic inequality

  • Yakubu Aliyu Bununu 7  

Part of the book series: Encyclopedia of the UN Sustainable Development Goals ((ENUNSDG))

290 Accesses

1 Citations

Definitions

Poverty is universally measured in monetary expenditure terms, and individuals that are considered poor are those living on less than US$1.25 per day. Poverty is however multifaceted as it includes the multitude of lack and deprivations that poor people are subjected to in their lives on a daily basis. These include but are not limited to disease and poor health conditions, illiteracy and lack of access to education, appalling living conditions, lack of access to economic opportunity and disempowerment, underemployment, vulnerability to violence, and exposure to hazardous environmental conditions (OPHI 2019 ). Thus, poverty reduction can be considered as the improvement of an individual’s or group’s monetary expenditure to an amount above the poverty line while improving access to education, healthcare, information, economic opportunities security of land-tenure, and all the other deprivations associated with it.

Introduction

The eradication of poverty is perhaps the only...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Craig D, Porter D (2003) Poverty reduction strategy papers: a new convergence. World Dev 31(1):53–69

Article   Google Scholar  

Crawford G, Abdulai A-G (2009) The World Bank and Ghana’s poverty reduction strategies: strengthening the state or consolidating neoliberalism? Labour Cap Soc 42(1 & 2):82

Google Scholar  

Cuesta J (2007) Political space, pro-poor growth, and poverty reduction strategy in Honduras: a story of missed opportunities. J Lat Am Stud 39:329–354

Dijkstra G (2005) The PRSP approach and the illusion of improved aid effectiveness: lessons from Bolivia, Honduras and Nicaragua. Dev Policy Rev 23(4): 443–464

Gottschalk R (2005) The macro content of PRSPs: assessing the need for a more flexible macroeconomic framework. Dev Policy Rev 23(4):419–443

IMF (2006) Cambodia: poverty reduction strategy paper. International Monetary Fund country report no. 06/266. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

IMF (2010) Nicaragua: poverty reduction strategy paper. International Monetary Fund country report no. 10/108. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

International Development Association (IDA) and International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2000a) Decision point document for the enhanced heavily indebted poor country initiative: Nicaragua. World Bank, Washington, DC

International Development Association (IDA) and International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2000b) Decision Point document for the enhanced heavily indebted poor country (HIPC) initiative: Honduras. World Bank, Washington, DC

IPCC (2014) Climate change 2014: impacts, adaptation, and vulnerability. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge/New York

Kingdom of Cambodia (2004) Cambodia National Poverty Reduction Strategy progress report. International Monetary Fund Country Report No. 06/266. International Monetary Fund Publication Services, Washington DC

Liu Q, Yu M, Wang X (2015) Poverty reduction within the framework of SDGs and post-2015 development agenda. Adv Clim Chang Res 6(2015):67–73. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.accre.2015.09.004

National Social Investment Office (NSIO) (2018) Investing in our people: a brief on the National Social Investment Programmes in Nigeria. National Social Investment Office, The Presidency, Abuja

OECD (Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2014) Poverty and climate change: reducing the vulnerability of the poor through adaptation. http://www.oecd.org/environment/cc/2502872.pdf

Ogwumike FO (1987) Poverty and basic needs: an approach to development in Nigeria. Unpublished PhD thesis, Department of Economics, University of Ibadan

Ogwumike FO (1995) The effects of macro-level government policies on rural development and poverty alleviation in Nigeria. Ib J Soc Sci 1(1):85–101

Ogwumike FO (1998) Poverty alleviation strategies in Nigeria. In: Measuring and monitoring poverty in Nigeria, Proceedings of the seventh annual conference of the Zonal Research Units of the Central Bank of Nigeria, Abuja, Nigeria

Ogwumike FO (2001) An appraisal of poverty reduction strategies in Nigeria. Cent Bank Nigeria Econ Financ Rev 39(4):45–71. Central Bank of Nigeria

Ogwumike FO, Aromolaran AB (2000) Poverty dynamics in Nigeria. In: Proceedings of the seventh annual conference of the Zonal Research Units of the Central Bank of Nigeria. Central Bank of Nigeria, Abuja

Oladeji SI, Abiola AG (1998) Poverty alleviation with economic growth strategy: prospects and challenges in contemporary Nigeria. Niger J Econ Soc Stud 40(1):19–33

Oxford Poverty and Human Development Index (OPHI) (2019) Policy – a multidimensional approach – what is multidimensional poverty? https://ophi.org.uk/policy/multidimensional-poverty-index/ . Accessed 22 Aug 2019

Peck J, Theodore N (2010) Recombinant workfare across the Americas. Geoforum 41(1):195

Ruckert A (2007) Producing neoliberal hegemony? A neo-Gramscian analysis of the poverty reduction strategy in Nicaragua. Stud Polit Econ 79(Spring):91–118

Ruckert A (2009) A decade of poverty reduction strategies in Latin America: empowering or disciplining the poor? Labour Cap Soc 42(1 & 2):56. JSTOR 2009

Sumner A (2006) In search of the Post-Washington (dis)consensus: the missing content of PRSPs. Third World Q 27(8):1401–1412

UN (United Nations) (2012) The future we want. Rio+20 United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development. http://www.un.org/en/sustainablefuture/

UN (United Nations) (2013) A new global partnership: eradicate poverty and transform economics through sustainable development. United Nations Publication, New York. https://sustainabledevelopment.un.org/content/documents/8932013-05%20%20HLP%20Report%20%20A%20New%20Global%20Partnership.pdf

UN (United Nations) (2014a) Report of the open working group of the General Assembly on Sustainable Development Goals. A/68/970. http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol¼A/68/970

UN (United Nations) (2014b) The road to dignity by 2030: ending poverty, transforming all lives and protecting the planet. A/69/700. http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol¼A/69/700&amp%3bamp%3bLang¼E

UNDESA (2018) World urbanization prospects: the 2018 revision. United Nations Department of Social and Economic Affairs. https://www.un.org/development/desa/publications/2018-revision-of-world-urbanization-prospects.html

World Bank (2000) World development report 2000/2000: attacking poverty. World Bank, Washington, DC

Book   Google Scholar  

World Bank, IMF (2005) The poverty reduction strategy initiative: findings from 10 country case studies of World Bank and IMF support. World Bank Operations and Evaluation Department and IMF Independent Evaluation Office. The World Bank, Washington DC

World Poverty Clock (2018) The percentage of Nigerians living in extreme poverty could increase by 2030. World Data Lab. https://worldpoverty.io/blog/index.php?r=12 . Retrieved 03/02/2019

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Urban and Regional Planning, Ahmadu Bello University, Zaria, Nigeria

Yakubu Aliyu Bununu

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yakubu Aliyu Bununu .

Editor information

Editors and affiliations.

European School of Sustainability, Hamburg University of Applied Sciences, Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany

Walter Leal Filho

Center for Neuroscience & Cell Biology, University of Coimbra, Coimbra, Portugal

Anabela Marisa Azul

Faculty of Engineering and Architecture, Passo Fundo University Faculty of Engineering and Architecture, Passo Fundo, Brazil

Luciana Brandli

Istinye University, Istanbul, Turkey

Pinar Gökcin Özuyar

International Centre for Thriving, University of Chester, Chester, UK

Section Editor information

School of Sustainability Arizona State University, Tempe, USA

Rimjhim M Aggarwal

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Cite this entry.

Bununu, Y.A. (2020). Poverty Reduction: Concept, Approaches, and Case Studies. In: Leal Filho, W., Azul, A., Brandli, L., Özuyar, P., Wall, T. (eds) Decent Work and Economic Growth. Encyclopedia of the UN Sustainable Development Goals. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-71058-7_31-1

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-71058-7_31-1

Received : 23 August 2019

Accepted : 08 September 2019

Published : 10 January 2020

Publisher Name : Springer, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-319-71058-7

Online ISBN : 978-3-319-71058-7

eBook Packages : Springer Reference Earth and Environm. Science Reference Module Physical and Materials Science Reference Module Earth and Environmental Sciences

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

Featured Topics

Featured series.

A series of random questions answered by Harvard experts.

Explore the Gazette

Read the latest.

Exterior of Tiffany flagship

For this ring, I thee sue 

Cass R. Sunstein (left) speaks with Benjamin Eidelson, Professor of Law, on his new book "Campus Free Speech."

Speech is never totally free

Lined up electric vehicle cars.

EVs fight warming but are costly. So why aren’t we driving $10,000 Chinese imports?

case study on economic inequality

The costs of inequality: Education’s the one key that rules them all

When there’s inequity in learning, it’s usually baked into life, Harvard analysts say

Corydon Ireland

Harvard Correspondent

Third in a series on what Harvard scholars are doing to identify and understand inequality, in seeking solutions to one of America’s most vexing problems.

Before Deval Patrick ’78, J.D. ’82, was the popular and successful two-term governor of Massachusetts, before he was managing director of high-flying Bain Capital, and long before he was Harvard’s most recent Commencement speaker , he was a poor black schoolchild in the battered housing projects of Chicago’s South Side.

case study on economic inequality

The odds of his escaping a poverty-ridden lifestyle, despite innate intelligence and drive, were long. So how did he help mold his own narrative and triumph over baked-in societal inequality ? Through education.

“Education has been the path to better opportunity for generations of American strivers, no less for me,” Patrick said in an email when asked how getting a solid education, in his case at Milton Academy and at Harvard, changed his life.

“What great teachers gave me was not just the skills to take advantage of new opportunities, but the ability to imagine what those opportunities could be. For a kid from the South Side of Chicago, that’s huge.”

If inequality starts anywhere, many scholars agree, it’s with faulty education. Conversely, a strong education can act as the bejeweled key that opens gates through every other aspect of inequality , whether political, economic , racial, judicial, gender- or health-based.

Simply put, a top-flight education usually changes lives for the better. And yet, in the world’s most prosperous major nation, it remains an elusive goal for millions of children and teenagers.

Plateau on educational gains

The revolutionary concept of free, nonsectarian public schools spread across America in the 19th century. By 1970, America had the world’s leading educational system, and until 1990 the gap between minority and white students, while clear, was narrowing.

But educational gains in this country have plateaued since then, and the gap between white and minority students has proven stubbornly difficult to close, says Ronald Ferguson, adjunct lecturer in public policy at Harvard Kennedy School (HKS) and faculty director of Harvard’s Achievement Gap Initiative. That gap extends along class lines as well.

“What great teachers gave me was not just the skills to take advantage of new opportunities, but the ability to imagine what those opportunities could be. For a kid from the South Side of Chicago, that’s huge.” — Deval Patrick

In recent years, scholars such as Ferguson, who is an economist, have puzzled over the ongoing achievement gap and what to do about it, even as other nations’ school systems at first matched and then surpassed their U.S. peers. Among the 34 market-based, democracy-leaning countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), the United States ranks around 20th annually, earning average or below-average grades in reading, science, and mathematics.

By eighth grade, Harvard economist Roland G. Fryer Jr. noted last year, only 44 percent of American students are proficient in reading and math. The proficiency of African-American students, many of them in underperforming schools, is even lower.

“The position of U.S. black students is truly alarming,” wrote Fryer, the Henry Lee Professor of Economics, who used the OECD rankings as a metaphor for minority standing educationally. “If they were to be considered a country, they would rank just below Mexico in last place.”

Harvard Graduate School of Education (HGSE) Dean James E. Ryan, a former public interest lawyer, says geography has immense power in determining educational opportunity in America. As a scholar, he has studied how policies and the law affect learning, and how conditions are often vastly unequal.

His book “Five Miles Away, A World Apart” (2010) is a case study of the disparity of opportunity in two Richmond, Va., schools, one grimly urban and the other richly suburban. Geography, he says, mirrors achievement levels.

A ZIP code as predictor of success

“Right now, there exists an almost ironclad link between a child’s ZIP code and her chances of success,” said Ryan. “Our education system, traditionally thought of as the chief mechanism to address the opportunity gap, instead too often reflects and entrenches existing societal inequities.”

Urban schools demonstrate the problem. In New York City, for example, only 8 percent of black males graduating from high school in 2014 were prepared for college-level work, according to the CUNY Institute for Education Policy, with Latinos close behind at 11 percent. The preparedness rates for Asians and whites — 48 and 40 percent, respectively — were unimpressive too, but nonetheless were firmly on the other side of the achievement gap.

case study on economic inequality

In some impoverished urban pockets, the racial gap is even larger. In Washington, D.C., 8 percent of black eighth-graders are proficient in math, while 80 percent of their white counterparts are.

Fryer said that in kindergarten black children are already 8 months behind their white peers in learning. By third grade, the gap is bigger, and by eighth grade is larger still.

According to a recent report by the Education Commission of the States, black and Hispanic students in kindergarten through 12th grade perform on a par with the white students who languish in the lowest quartile of achievement.

There was once great faith and hope in America’s school systems. The rise of quality public education a century ago “was probably the best public policy decision Americans have ever made because it simultaneously raised the whole growth rate of the country for most of the 20th century, and it leveled the playing field,” said Robert Putnam, the Peter and Isabel Malkin Professor of Public Policy at HKS, who has written several best-selling books touching on inequality, including “Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of the American Community” and “Our Kids: The American Dream in Crisis.”

Historically, upward mobility in America was characterized by each generation becoming better educated than the previous one, said Harvard economist Lawrence Katz. But that trend, a central tenet of the nation’s success mythology, has slackened, particularly for minorities.

“Thirty years ago, the typical American had two more years of schooling than their parents. Today, we have the most educated group of Americans, but they only have about .4 more years of schooling, so that’s one part of mobility not keeping up in the way we’ve invested in education in the past,” Katz said.

As globalization has transformed and sometimes undercut the American economy, “education is not keeping up,” he said. “There’s continuing growth of demand for more abstract, higher-end skills” that schools aren’t delivering, “and then that feeds into a weakening of institutions like unions and minimum-wage protections.”

“The position of U.S. black students is truly alarming.” — Roland G. Fryer Jr.

Fryer is among a diffuse cohort of Harvard faculty and researchers using academic tools to understand the achievement gap and the many reasons behind problematic schools. His venue is the Education Innovation Laboratory , where he is faculty director.

“We use big data and causal methods,” he said of his approach to the issue.

Fryer, who is African-American, grew up poor in a segregated Florida neighborhood. He argues that outright discrimination has lost its power as a primary driver behind inequality, and uses economics as “a rational forum” for discussing social issues.

Better schools to close the gap

Fryer set out in 2004 to use an economist’s data and statistical tools to answer why black students often do poorly in school compared with whites. His years of research have convinced him that good schools would close the education gap faster and better than addressing any other social factor, including curtailing poverty and violence, and he believes that the quality of kindergarten through grade 12 matters above all.

Supporting his belief is research that says the number of schools achieving excellent student outcomes is a large enough sample to prove that much better performance is possible. Despite the poor performance by many U.S. states, some have shown that strong results are possible on a broad scale. For instance, if Massachusetts were a nation, it would rate among the best-performing countries.

At HGSE, where Ferguson is faculty co-chair as well as director of the Achievement Gap Initiative, many factors are probed. In the past 10 years, Ferguson, who is African-American, has studied every identifiable element contributing to unequal educational outcomes. But lately he is looking hardest at improving children’s earliest years, from infancy to age 3.

In addition to an organization he founded called the Tripod Project , which measures student feedback on learning, he launched the Boston Basics project in August, with support from the Black Philanthropy Fund, Boston’s mayor, and others. The first phase of the outreach campaign, a booklet, videos, and spot ads, starts with advice to parents of children age 3 or younger.

“Maximize love, manage stress” is its mantra and its foundational imperative, followed by concepts such as “talk, sing, and point.” (“Talking,” said Ferguson, “is teaching.”) In early childhood, “The difference in life experiences begins at home.”

At age 1, children score similarly

Fryer and Ferguson agree that the achievement gap starts early. At age 1, white, Asian, black, and Hispanic children score virtually the same in what Ferguson called “skill patterns” that measure cognitive ability among toddlers, including examining objects, exploring purposefully, and “expressive jabbering.” But by age 2, gaps are apparent, with black and Hispanic children scoring lower in expressive vocabulary, listening comprehension, and other indicators of acuity. That suggests educational achievement involves more than just schooling, which typically starts at age 5.

Key factors in the gap, researchers say, include poverty rates (which are three times higher for blacks than for whites), diminished teacher and school quality, unsettled neighborhoods, ineffective parenting, personal trauma, and peer group influence, which only strengthens as children grow older.

case study on economic inequality

“Peer beliefs and values,” said Ferguson, get “trapped in culture” and are compounded by the outsized influence of peers and the “pluralistic ignorance” they spawn. Fryer’s research, for instance, says that the reported stigma of “acting white” among many black students is true. The better they do in school, the fewer friends they have — while for whites who are perceived as smarter, there’s an opposite social effect.

The researchers say that family upbringing matters, in all its crisscrossing influences and complexities, and that often undercuts minority children, who can come from poor or troubled homes. “Unequal outcomes,” he said, “are from, to a large degree, inequality in life experiences.”

Trauma also subverts achievement, whether through family turbulence, street violence, bullying, sexual abuse, or intermittent homelessness. Such factors can lead to behaviors in school that reflect a pervasive form of childhood post-traumatic stress disorder.

[gz_sidebar align=”left”]

Possible solutions to educational inequality:

  • Access to early learning
  • Improved K-12 schools
  • More family mealtimes
  • Reinforced learning at home
  • Data-driven instruction
  • Longer school days, years
  • Respect for school rules
  • Small-group tutoring
  • High expectations of students
  • Safer neighborhoods

[/gz_sidebar]

At Harvard Law School, both the Trauma and Learning Policy Initiative and the Education Law Clinic marshal legal aid resources for parents and children struggling with trauma-induced school expulsions and discipline issues.

At Harvard Business School, Karim R. Lakhani, an associate professor who is a crowdfunding expert and a champion of open-source software, has studied how unequal racial and economic access to technology has worked to widen the achievement gap.

At Harvard’s Project Zero, a nonprofit called the Family Dinner Project is scraping away at the achievement gap from the ground level by pushing for families to gather around the meal table, which traditionally was a lively and comforting artifact of nuclear families, stable wages, close-knit extended families, and culturally shared values.

Lynn Barendsen, the project’s executive director, believes that shared mealtimes improve reading skills, spur better grades and larger vocabularies, and fuel complex conversations. Interactive mealtimes provide a learning experience of their own, she said, along with structure, emotional support, a sense of safety, and family bonding. Even a modest jump in shared mealtimes could boost a child’s academic performance, she said.

“We’re not saying families have to be perfect,” she said, acknowledging dinnertime impediments like full schedules, rudimentary cooking skills, the lure of technology, and the demands of single parenting. “The perfect is the enemy of the good.”

Whether poring over Fryer’s big data or Barendsen’s family dinner project, there is one commonality for Harvard researchers dealing with inequality in education: the issue’s vast complexity. The achievement gap is a creature of interlocking factors that are hard to unpack constructively.

Going wide, starting early

With help from faculty co-chair and Jesse Climenko Professor of Law Charles J. Ogletree, the Achievement Gap Initiative is analyzing the factors that make educational inequality such a complex puzzle: home and family life, school environments, teacher quality, neighborhood conditions, peer interaction, and the fate of “all those wholesome things,” said Ferguson. The latter include working hard in school, showing respect, having nice friends, and following the rules, traits that can be “elements of a 21st-century movement for equality.”

case study on economic inequality

In the end, best practices to create strong schools will matter most, said Fryer.

He called high-quality education “the new civil rights battleground” in a landmark 2010 working paper for the Handbook of Labor Economics called “Racial Inequality in the 21st Century: The Declining Significance of Discrimination.”

Fryer tapped 10 large data sets on children 8 months to 17 years old. He studied charter schools, scouring for standards that worked. He champions longer school days and school years, data-driven instruction, small-group tutoring, high expectations, and a school culture that prizes human capital — all just “a few simple investments,” he wrote in the working paper. “The challenge for the future is to take these examples to scale” across the country.

How long would closing the gap take with a national commitment to do so? A best-practices experiment that Fryer conducted at low-achieving high schools in Houston closed the gap in math skills within three years, and narrowed the reading achievement gap by a third.

“You don’t need Superman for this,” he said, referring to a film about Geoffrey Canada and his Harlem Children’s Zone, just high-quality schools for everyone, to restore 19th-century educator Horace Mann’s vision of public education as society’s “balance-wheel.”

Last spring, Fryer, still only 38, won the John Bates Clark medal, the most prestigious award in economics after the Nobel Prize. He was a MacArthur Fellow in 2011, became a tenured Harvard professor in 2007, was named to the prestigious Society of Fellows at age 25. He had a classically haphazard childhood, but used school to learn, grow, and prosper. Gradually, he developed a passion for social science that could help him answer what was going wrong in black lives because of educational inequality.

With his background and talent, Fryer has a dramatically unique perspective on inequality and achievement, and he has something else: a seemingly counterintuitive sense that these conditions will improve, once bad schools learn to get better. Discussing the likelihood of closing the achievement gap if Americans have the political and organizational will to do so, Fryer said, “I see nothing but optimism.”

Correction: An earlier version of this story inaccurately portrayed details of Dr. Fryer’s background.

Illustration by Kathleen M.G. Howlett. Harvard staff writer Christina Pazzanese contributed to this report.

Next Tuesday: Inequality in health care

Share this article

You might like.

Unhappy suitor wants $70,000 engagement gift back. Now court must decide whether 

Cass R. Sunstein (left) speaks with Benjamin Eidelson, Professor of Law, on his new book "Campus Free Speech."

Cass Sunstein suggests universities look to First Amendment as they struggle to craft rules in wake of disruptive protests

Lined up electric vehicle cars.

Experts say tension between trade, green-tech policies hampers climate change advances; more targeted response needed

Harvard releases race data for Class of 2028

Cohort is first to be impacted by Supreme Court’s admissions ruling

Parkinson’s may take a ‘gut-first’ path

Damage to upper GI lining linked to future risk of Parkinson’s disease, says new study

Professor tailored AI tutor to physics course. Engagement doubled.

Preliminary findings inspire other large Harvard classes to test approach this fall

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here .

Loading metrics

Open Access

Peer-reviewed

Research Article

Tracking the impact of COVID-19 on economic inequality at high frequency

Contributed equally to this work with: Oriol Aspachs, Ruben Durante, Alberto Graziano, Josep Mestres, Marta Reynal-Querol, Jose G. Montalvo

Roles Conceptualization, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – original draft

Affiliation Caixabank Research, Caixabank, Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain

Roles Conceptualization, Funding acquisition, Investigation, Writing – original draft

Affiliations Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra (UPF), Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain, ICREA, Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain, Institute for Political Economy and Governance (IPEG), Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain, Barcelona Graduate School of Economics (BGSE), Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain

Roles Data curation, Formal analysis, Software

Roles Conceptualization, Data curation, Investigation, Software, Writing – original draft

Roles Funding acquisition, Investigation, Methodology

Roles Conceptualization, Formal analysis, Funding acquisition, Methodology, Project administration, Software, Writing – original draft

* E-mail: [email protected]

Affiliations Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra (UPF), Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain, Institute for Political Economy and Governance (IPEG), Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain, Barcelona Graduate School of Economics (BGSE), Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain

ORCID logo

  • Oriol Aspachs, 
  • Ruben Durante, 
  • Alberto Graziano, 
  • Josep Mestres, 
  • Marta Reynal-Querol, 
  • Jose G. Montalvo

PLOS

  • Published: March 31, 2021
  • https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121
  • Reader Comments

Table 1

Pandemics have historically had a significant impact on economic inequality. However, official inequality statistics are only available at low frequency and with considerable delay, which challenges policymakers in their objective to mitigate inequality and fine-tune public policies. We show that using data from bank records it is possible to measure economic inequality at high frequency. The approach proposed in this paper allows measuring, timely and accurately, the impact on inequality of fast-unfolding crises, like the COVID-19 pandemic. Applying this approach to data from a representative sample of over three million residents of Spain we find that, absent government intervention, inequality would have increased by almost 30% in just one month. The granularity of the data allows analyzing with great detail the sources of the increases in inequality. In the Spanish case we find that it is primarily driven by job losses and wage cuts experienced by low-wage earners. Government support, in particular extended unemployment insurance and benefits for furloughed workers, were generally effective at mitigating the increase in inequality, though less so among young people and foreign-born workers. Therefore, our approach provides knowledge on the evolution of inequality at high frequency, the effectiveness of public policies in mitigating the increase of inequality and the subgroups of the population most affected by the changes in inequality. This information is fundamental to fine-tune public policies on the wake of a fast-moving pandemic like the COVID-19.

Citation: Aspachs O, Durante R, Graziano A, Mestres J, Reynal-Querol M, Montalvo JG (2021) Tracking the impact of COVID-19 on economic inequality at high frequency. PLoS ONE 16(3): e0249121. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121

Editor: Shihe Fu, Xiamen University, CHINA

Received: September 18, 2020; Accepted: March 11, 2021; Published: March 31, 2021

Copyright: © 2021 Aspachs et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License , which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.

Data Availability: Data cannot be shared publicly because they are owned by a third-party commercial bank (Caixabank), and there are legal restrictions to their use. The Legal Services of the bank accepted the use of the microdata only to researchers belonging to their Research Unit. Therefore, the researchers of the team that did not belong to Caixabank Research could not access the microdata. They contributed with the conceptualization of the research, the writing of code, the proposal of different empirical exercises and the writing of the manuscript. Data can be made available by Caixabank Research (contact via [email protected] ) to professional researchers who meet the criteria to access confidential data. Researchers interested in obtaining access to the data are required to submit a written application to Caixabank Research with a detailed research proposal consisting in a research question and motivation, information on the researcher CV, and a detailed explanation of the data needed, and the aggregation criteria to protect the anonymity of the registers. The authors will provide assistance to any researcher willing to analyze the data for replication purposes.

Funding: JGM & MRQ: ECO2017-82696P, Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation ( http://www.ciencia.gob.es/ ); CEX 2019-000915S Severo Ochoa Program for Centers of Excellence ( http://www.ciencia.gob.es/ ). The Research Department of CaixaBank provided support in the form of salaries for authors OA, AG and, JM. The specific roles of these authors are articulated in the ‘author contributions’ section. JGM, MRQ and RD acknowledge the financial support of the "Ayudas Fundación BBVA a Equipos de Investigación Científica SARS-CoV-2 y COVID-19.” The funders had no role in the study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

Competing interests: OA, AG, and JM are employees of the Research Department of CaixaBank. There are no patents, products in development or marketed products to declare. This does not alter our adherence to PLOS ONE policies on sharing data and materials.

Introduction

The COVID-19 pandemic has had a massive impact on economic activity around the globe. To tackle the economic consequences of the pandemic, most governments have used a combination of family income support and credit facilities for firms. In particular, expanded unemployment insurance and furlough schemes have been adopted to stabilize the income of the workers, and contain the impact of the crisis on consumption and economic inequality. The concern is that a surge in inequality may erode social cohesion and spur support for populist or even undemocratic views.

Yet, how appropriate and effective these policies are remains unclear, mainly due to a lack of reliable indicators allowing to track economic activity at a fine temporal resolution. Indeed, most official statistics on inequality are available only at yearly frequency and often with long delays. This limits the ability of policymakers to rapidly adjust their responses in the effort to “flatten the recession curve” [ 1 ] after flattening the infection curve.

The COVID-19 has pushed new international initiatives to track economic activity in real time [ 2 – 6 ]. Researchers analyze the impact of economic stimulus packages to mitigate the effect of the COVID-19 epidemic on economic activity using high-frequency administrative data. Two examples are the effect on aggregate employment of the Paycheck Protection Program of the US [ 7 ] or the effect on consumption of the stimulus checks sent by the US Administration [ 8 ] using the data from financial aggregation and service apps [ 9 – 12 ].

One characteristic aspect of pandemics is their impact on inequality [ 13 , 14 ]. However, official inequality measures are calculated with long lags and low frequency. In the context of a fast-moving pandemic it is important to have a high-frequency measure of inequality to evaluate the mitigating effect of policy measures. This is particularly important in countries, like Spain, that suffered very intensively the financial crisis of 2008 and that have experienced an important increase in inequality since then. This process increased the support for populist parties, which in 2008 were not represented in the parliament and in 2020 accounted for 32.8% of the representatives in Congress. It is interesting to notice that inequality increased significantly from 2008 to 2012 but the process of growing political representation of populist parties happens mostly after 2013, even though inequality was decreasing since 2013. This seems to imply that there may be a threshold level of inequality that, once overcome, can trigger a set of popular grievances that persist over time, generating increasing support for populist parties. Therefore, a further increase in inequality, even in the short run, could imply reaching a level of inequality above the threshold that triggers future tension and political unrest. It could also ignite a process of increasing support for populist parties that could easily produce a significant deterioration of the institutional stability. Ultimately, this could have a long run effect on economic performance.

This paper uses bank account data and proposes a methodology to track the impact of government policies on inequality immediately after they are taken. Inequality is a multifaceted object and can concern dimensions as different as income, wealth, education etc. Our analysis focuses on wage inequality which, in countries with a high proportion of wage-earners, is a very precise indicator of overall income inequality (as we document for Spain). We do not look at wealth inequality mainly because, using information from just one financial institution, there is a high risk of not gauging a complete picture of the financial holdings of an individual. Bank account data have many advantages to study the effect of policy responses to the COVID-19 pandemic. They provide timely and reliable information on wages and government benefits. Being able to use very granular data, and to construct a high-frequency measure of inequality, allows to tailor policies to contain the increase of inequality in general, and by subgroups of the population classified by income level, gender, age, and county of birth.

Recent research has also used bank account data to study the evolution of different macro-magnitudes at very high frequency and, in particular, the effects of the pandemic on consumption [ 15 – 17 ]. Our contribution to this literature is threefold. First, and opposite to many papers in this literature [ 9 , 10 ], our sample is very representative of the population of Spanish wage-earners. As we show in next section, the distribution by gender and age are almost identical to the figures reported by the National Statistical Office. Second, and in contrast with a large part of the literature that uses banks accounts data, we are not analyzing the evolution of expenditure but the changes in the distribution of wages over time. Finally, the papers that have data on expenditure and income, like [ 16 ], deal with the issue of the sensitivity of consumption to income and do not consider the evolution of inequality, which is our basic objective.

We study empirically the evolution of inequality, before and after considering government support, comparing the period before the lockdown with the lockdown stage. We apply this methodology to data from a large Spanish bank. Spain is one of the countries most affected by the pandemic not only in terms of the number of people infected, but also regarding the economic impact. The comparison of the situation before and after the activation of the new policies of income support allows analyzing the effect of government interventions in the mitigation of inequality.

Using these bank account data, and our research design, we find that the largest impact of COVID-19 on inequality is transmitted through the movement of the distribution of salary changes among low wage earners. Second, we also find that most of the increase of inequality in the period after the beginning of the pandemic is mitigated by the action of the new extended unemployment benefits and furlough schemes activated by the government. There are no other changes in other government benefits during the period of analysis. We provide further details on the public income measures to support workers in the next section. Third we show that the policy response could not fully mitigate the large increase in inequality among young people and foreign-born individuals.

Materials and methods

We study the effect of COVID-19 on inequality using bank account data from CaixaBank, the second largest Spanish bank. Caixabank had monthly records on more than 3 million wage earners in 2020, and accounted for 27.1% of the wages, salaries and benefits deposited monthly in the Spanish financial sector. In Spain, differently from other countries like the US, the payment of the salaries or benefits using checks is a very rare event. Almost all the payments of salaries and benefits use direct deposits on bank accounts.

The wages and government benefits recorded by CaixaBank provide a large, precise and granular data source. Banks’ administrative data avoid most of the problems of surveys: there are no measurement errors or imperfect recollection mistakes, and they are obtained with short delays compared to surveys. For instance, the CaixaBank data provides the universe of wages through June 15, 2020 while the latest official measure of wage inequality in Spain, produced by the National Institute of Statistics, was published at the end of June of 2020, but referred to the situation in 2018.

The granularity of CaixaBank data allows also calculating inequality for subgroups of the population. Unlike other financial institutions, such as digital banks and personal finance management software, CaixaBank collects demographic information directly (gender, age, province, country of birth). We also provide a methodology to calculate monthly Gini indices and Lorentz curves, before and after accounting for public benefits, to analyze if the schemes to support workers temporarily out of the labor market are being effective at containing inequality.

The raw data are the wages and salaries deposited monthly at CaixaBank, and they present some challenges in order to construct wage inequality measures. We restrict our sample to accounts with either only one account holder or with multiple account co-holders but only one employer paying-in wages. This way, we ensure that payrolls or transfers recorded correspond to only one individual and avoid recording multiple payrolls or transfers from multiple account holders. In addition, we exclude from the sample those individuals who died during our period of study or who did not use the bank account for their usual financial transactions during the period. Finally, to ensure some stability on the sample of individuals studied, we require observing either wages or government benefits during two months (that is, in December 2019 and in January 2020) prior to the beginning of the period of study (February 2020). The S1 File explains all the details of our methodology to select the data.

Our reference sample includes individuals aged 16-64 who received either wages or unemployment benefits in December of 2019 and January of 2020. We follow those individuals in the months starting in February 2020. Since our main source of data is related with holding a bank account it is important to start analyzing the level of financial inclusion in Spain. The data of the Global Findex, the index of financial inclusion of the World Bank, shows that 97.6% of Spanish people over 15 years old holds a bank account when the average in high income countries is 93.7%.

We exclude the self-employed from our sample since it is difficult to calculate their net monthly income from bank account data: they receive payments from many different sources, and it is complicated to calculate expenses associated with their business. However, it is important to note that the proportion of wage earners among the Spanish working population was 84.4% in the first quarter of 2020 (Labor Force Survey of Spain, EPA). The relevance of wages as the main source of income can also be seen in the similarity of the inequality measures using income or gross wages. For instance, for the last period for which both measures are available, income inequality in Spain, measured by the Gini index, was 0.345 while wage inequality was 0.343.

Since most of the individuals in the sample are workers, to analyze its representativeness in terms of the distribution of wages we compare our data with the data of the latest Spanish National Statistical Office’s Wage Survey (Encuesta de Estructura Salarial, EES). For this purpose we consider the individuals in our sample who were working in February of 2020. First, we compare the distribution of individuals by gender and age with other sources. Table 1 summarizes the comparisons. In general, samples from digital banks and financial aggregation services have more young males than the general population. This is not the case with large and diversified traditional banks like our data source, CaixaBank. Table 1 shows that the gender and age distribution of our data is very similar to the working population.

thumbnail

  • PPT PowerPoint slide
  • PNG larger image
  • TIFF original image

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121.t001

In our sample, 54% of the individuals are male. This compares satisfactorily with the 52% of males in the sample of the last official survey (EES). In order to compare with more recent estimates, columns 3 and 4 include the proportions of males among employees in the Labor Force Survey of the last quarter of 2019 and first quarter of 2020. February of 2020 is between the last quarter of 2019 and the first quarter of 2020. The proportion of males is identical to the one in the EES and very close to the one in our sample. With respect to age, we also find that the proportions of workers in each age bracked in our sample are very similar to those reported in the EES and the EPA.

Fig 1 shows the distribution of the monthly wages of our sample compared with the distribution of monthly net salaries in the EES. The wages received by workers in their bank accounts are net of payroll taxes. In order to compare our data with the EES we have calculated the distribution of net salaries transforming the gross salaries of the EES into net salaries by subtracting social insurance payments and taxes withheld. The S1 File includes a detailed explanation of this transformation. Since there is a time difference between the last EES available and our data we have adjusted the wages by moving the whole distribution by the increase in the average wage since the last available EES. We can see that the histogram of the net wages of our sample is very well adjusted by the density estimation of the adjusted distribution of net salaries in the official wage survey. Both distributions are remarkably similar. The similarity of the distribution of wages, and also the characteristics of the workforce, confirms the representativeness of our sample.

thumbnail

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121.g001

Since the distributions are so similar it is not surprising to see that the quantile ratios used regularly to describe inequality are very similar in both distributions as shown in S1 Table in S1 File .

Government support schemes for workers

The public policy response to mitigate the impact of the COVID-19 crisis in Spain has been large, as in most developed countries. For a detailed description of the economic impact of COVID-19 on the Spanish economy and the public policy reaction see [ 18 ]. The Spanish government has deployed income and liquidity support measures that are expected to reach 3.7% of GDP in discretionary measures and around 15.6% of GDP in off-budget measures [ 19 ].

Income measures to support workers have consisted mostly in the deployment of a furlough scheme (“Expediente de Regulación Temporal de Empleo”, or ERTEs) that was scarcely used until then. This scheme consists in a temporary job suspension (or a reduction in working hours) that avoids dismissals while maintaining the employment relationship. The Spanish government facilitated the use of this ERTE scheme due to COVID-19 (considering coronavirus as a force majeure, etc.) and increased coverage to all workers affected by a temporary job suspension. In addition, the benefits received did not reduce future unemployment benefit entitlements.

In addition to the job retention scheme, the government facilitated and extended the coverage of unemployment benefits. Regular unemployment benefits require a minimum of 360 days of contract employment in the previous 6 years and its duration is proportional to the amount of time worked (up to 18 months). Due to the pandemic, however, special unemployment subsidies were created for those who exhausted their unemployment benefits.

Those workers affected by job retention schemes and by unemployment received unemployment benefit transfers, which normally amounts to 70% of their social security contribution base. The schemes ensured an income stream during the duration of the contract suspension or unemployment, although of a lower amount than the regular salary.

Public transfers programs partially compensated wage losses for those workers that received them. However, despite the increase in coverage not all affected workers were entitled or had the same degree of coverage. In particular, those workers already unemployed before the pandemic or in temporary contracts that expired might not have had the right to unemployment benefits or only to reduced amounts. In addition, many of the beneficiaries experienced several months of delay before actually receiving their unemployment benefits in their bank accounts. All these developments might have affected the effectiveness of the government support to reduce inequality. This is of particular relevance in a country as Spain, which suffers from a very high labour market duality. In particular, subgroups of the population like young and foreign-born individuals are most likely to be in temporary contracts, and thus more heavily affected.

Large effect of the shutdown on pre-benefits inequality mostly due to low wage earners

To analyze the role of government benefits on inequality our analysis considers two scenarios: pre- and post-government benefits. In the pre-benefits scenario, we consider monthly wages before taking into account the benefits. The post-benefits scenario also considers unemployment insurance benefits, subsidies and furlough schemes.

Fig 2 shows the distribution of changes in pre-benefit wages between February and April 2020 (i.e., before vs. during the lockdown), represented by the solid lines. The x-axis reports the percentage change in wages experienced between the two months, while the y-axis reports the share of account holders in each category. The dashed lines represent the distribution for the same months of 2019, i.e., prior to the pandemic. The top left panel reports the distribution for the entire sample; the other panels report the distribution for each of five wage brackets (measured as of February of 2020): i) the interval between 900 to 1,000 euros, which includes the 25th percentile of the wage distribution; the interval between 1,200 to 1,300 euros, which includes the median; the interval between 1,700 to 1,800 euros, which includes the 75th percentile; the interval between 2,900 and 3,000 euros, which includes the 95 percentile, and the interval between 4,700 and 4,800, which represents the top 1%.

thumbnail

Pre-benefits scenario. Comparing 2020 and 2019.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121.g002

Several interesting facts emerge from Fig 2 . First, in 2020 the probability mass of the no-change interval is about half than in 2019. Compared to 2019, in 2020 a sizeable portion has moved to the no-income category. Furthermore, and most interestingly, in 2020 the probability of shifting to the no-income category is higher for individuals in the lower wage brackets.

Another noticeable aspect is that a substantial share of the highest wage earners experience a drastic wage reduction in April relative to February. This seasonal pattern, observed both in 2019 and 2020, is due to the payment of bonuses which occurs in February, and reaches over 30% for the top earners in our sample (i.e., the top 0.01%, not shown in the figure). There is no evidence of an analogous pattern for low wage earners.

S1 Fig in S1 File shows the difference in payments received by account holders between April and February after accounting for extended unemployment insurance and other benefits. Compared to the pre-benefits wages depicted in Fig 2 , the shift to the no-income category is much less pronounced. There is still a large wage reduction for high earners who are largely unaffected by government transfers.

S2 Fig in S1 File compares in the same graph all the levels of initial wages, before and after government benefits, to facilitate the comparisons.

To account for seasonality Fig 3 shows the difference in the proportion of changes in salaries between April and March of 2020 net of the the difference between the same two months in 2019. The S1 File shows the precise transformation to deal with seasonality. When seasonality is controlled for, the effect of the February bonuses for high wage earners disappears. Interestingly, the effect of the pandemic on pre-transfer earnings is very different for low and high wages. For wages below 1,300 euros the lower mass in the no-change brackets is associated with a corresponding shift to no-income category. The importance of the decline of employment for the lowest-income workers is common to other countries like the US [ 20 ]. For wages above 1,700 euros, instead, the lower mass in the no-change brackets is associated with a higher share of individuals experiencing small wage cuts. S3 Fig in S1 File shows the changes for all wage categories in the same figure.

thumbnail

April vs February—2020 vs 2019.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121.g003

To summarize the evolution of inequality we compute the Gini index. The S1 File presents a discussion of its calculation. Fig 4 Panel (a) depicts the evolution of the Gini index between February and May for 2020 and 2019, respectively. Both the pre- and post-benefits curves are basically parallel until April 2020, when the pre-benefits Gini index increases considerably while the post-benefit one only moderately. In May 2020 the pre-benefits Gini index remains very high, while the post-benefits index returns to the pre-pandemic level. From February until April of 2020 the pre-benefits Gini index increased close to 0.11 points. This implies a 25% increase in just two months. To evaluate the statistical significance of this large movement in the Gini index we can calculate the confidence intervals around our estimate. There are basically two possible procedures: using a Jakknife or a WLS estimator [ 21 ]. The S1 File describes the calculation of the standard error of the Gini index using a WLS estimator. As expected, given our large sample size, the standard error is very low (0.0002). This implies that the increase of 0.11 points observed in the Gini index between February and April of 2020 is highly statistically significant (well over the level of significance of 1%). Since the confidence intervals are tiny they cannot be visualized in the figures.

thumbnail

(a) Gini index (b) Theil index ( α = 1) (c) Lorentz curve: Pre-benefits, 2020 (d) Lorentz curve: Post-benefits, 2020.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121.g004

To confirm the robustness of the documented pattern to alternative measures of inequality, in Fig 4 Panel (b) we show the evolution of the Theil index, an inequality measure related to the concept of entropy and to Shannon’s index. The S1 File discusses the computation of this index. The Theil index shows a pattern very similar to the Gini index: a sizeable increase in March for both the pre- and post-benefits distribution which persists in April for the pre-benefit measure but not for the post-benefit one.

Panels (c) and (d) of Fig 4 show the changes in the pre- and post-benefits Lorenz curves respectively for every month between February and May 2020. It is apparent that, for the pre-benefits curve, the downward movement accelerates in April and stabilizes in May, while, for the post-benefit curve, the evolution is smoother.

Within group inequality post benefits has increased among young and foreign-born people

Given the granularity of the data we can also analyze the evolution of inequality within different subgroups of the population, differentiating by gender, age, and country of origin. Panel (a) in Fig 5 shows that there are not major differences in within inequality of males and females before the shock. The magnitude of the increase in the Gini index after the beginning of the pandemic is similar across genders before public transfers, but slightly higher for females in the post-benefits case.

thumbnail

(a) By gender. (b) By age group. (c) By place of birth.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121.g005

Panel (b) of Fig 5 shows the evolution of inequality for different age groups. For the youngest cohort (i.e., 16 to 29 years old), there is a considerable increase in the Gini index for pre-transfer earnings. The other groups also experience an increase in inequality though much smaller than for the young. The spike in the Gini index for the young is mitigated when considering the distribution of post-benefit earnings. Yet, the level of post-benefits inequality for this group is still remarkable, both in absolute and in relative terms. Such increase is arguably related to the fact that young workers account for a high proportion of temporary jobs in low wage occupations.

Panel (c) of Fig 5 shows the evolution of the Gini index separately for foreign-born individuals and for natives. As of January 1st 2020, foreign-born individuals represented 14.77% of the total Spanish resident population. Looking at the distribution of pre-benefits earnings, it is clear that inequality increases much more among foreign born than among natives. Such increase is less pronounced when looking at the post-benefits distribution, though, in this case as well, the Gini index for foreign born is significantly higher than for natives.

Interesting differences emerge when dividing foreign-born individuals by the per capita GDP level of the country of origin. For example, as shown in S4 Fig in S1 File , while post-benefits inequality decreases over time for both natives and foreign-born from high-income countries, it remains high for foreign-born from low-income countries.

The disproportionate increase in post-benefit inequality among poorer migrants attests to their vulnerability in times of crisis as their social welfare net is thinner. Foreign born workers from low income countries tend to have occupations with low salaries, and a high proportion of temporary jobs. In many cases they work without a formal contract which means that they cannot prove they were working before the pandemic and, therefore, they cannot get the benefits that other workers get. On the other hand expatriates from high income countries still enjoy a high salary.

Finally, inequality increases more in regions that rely heavily on tourism (e.g., Balearic and Canary Islands) than in other parts of the country (S5 Fig in S1 File ). This is not surprising since the touristic sector is characterized by a high proportion of low wage workers who, as shown above, are the ones most affected by the job losses and wage cuts caused by the pandemic.

The financial crisis of 2008 generated a large increase in inequality in many countries. When some countries were still trying to recover from the financial crisis a new shock, the COVID-19, has hit the economy. Recent research shows that social distancing laws are not responsible for the economic harm [ 15 ] and the responses to emergency declarations are strongly differentiated by income [ 22 ]. In this paper we show that the economic impact is also very heterogeneous by income level which, in turn, is reflected in large increases in inequality before governments policy response.

Our findings contribute to a recent literature on the measurement of economic indicators in real-time, or at very high frequency. Most of the economic research on the impact of COVID-19 has concentrated on its effect on consumption [ 6 , 8 , 15 – 17 ]. We present evidence on the impact of COVID-19 on economic inequality. Our findings show that, before accounting for extended unemployment insurance and furlough benefits, the economic impact of the pandemic caused a large increase of inequality. After considering public benefits the effect of the crisis on inequality is mitigated. We show how bank account data of a representative financial institution can be used to track inequality and monitor the effect of economic polity on its evolution. In contrast with some previous research that uses data on personal finance websites and bank accounts, our data replicates very precisely the distribution of the population of wage earners.

We present evidence that shows a very heterogeneous impact of the pandemic on inequality by income level, age and country of birth of the individuals. Our methodology could be applied to many other countries that have introduced income-support schemes similar to the ones considered in Spain (furlough benefits and extended unemployment insurance). Tracking, at high frequency, the effect of policy responses on inequality allows tuning the policy instruments to mitigate inequality, targeting the groups that contribute the most to the increase of inequality.

Supporting information

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0249121.s001

Acknowledgments

We want to thank Miguel Angel Barcia for his helpful suggestions. Daniele Alimonti provided excellent research assistance.

  • 1. Gourinchas PO. “Flattening the Pandemic and Recession Curves” in Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever, Ed. Baldwin R., Weder di Mauro B. (Chapter 2, 31–40). CEPR Press, London, UK), 2020.
  • View Article
  • Google Scholar
  • 14. Scheidel Walter. The great leveler: Violence and the history of inequality from the stone age to the twenty-first century. Princeton University Press, 2018.
  • 16. Hacioglu S., Kanzig D., and Surico P. The distributional impact of the pandemic. CEPR Discussion Paper 15101, 2020.
  • 17. Bachas N., Ganong P., Noel P., Vara J., Wong A., Farrell D., et al. Initial impact of the pandemic on consumer behavior: evidence from linked income, spending, and savings data. NBER Working Paper 27617, 2020.
  • 19. IMF. Spain 2020 article iv consultation. 2020.

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • View all journals
  • Explore content
  • About the journal
  • Publish with us
  • Sign up for alerts
  • Open access
  • Published: 30 January 2018

What has economics got to do with it? The impact of socioeconomic factors on mental health and the case for collective action

  • Anna Macintyre 1 ,
  • Daniel Ferris 2 ,
  • Briana Gonçalves 3 &
  • Neil Quinn 1  

Palgrave Communications volume  4 , Article number:  10 ( 2018 ) Cite this article

64k Accesses

62 Citations

96 Altmetric

Metrics details

  • Social policy

A clear link exists between social and economic inequality and poor mental health. There is a social gradient in mental health, and higher levels of income inequality are linked to higher prevalence of mental illness. Despite this, in the late 20th and early 21st century, psychiatric and psychological perspectives have dominated mental health research and policy, obscuring root socioeconomic contributors. Drawing on contemporary research on the social determinants of mental health, with particular reference to Europe and the U.S., this paper argues that a sharper focus on socioeconomic factors is required in research and policy to address inequalities in mental health. Current attempts to move this direction include: evaluation of the impact of economic policies on mental health, community-based partnerships, increased professional awareness and advocacy on socioeconomic factors. This necessitates greater understanding of the barriers to such actions. This paper argues that advancing ‘upstream’ approaches to population mental health requires an interdisciplinary research vision that supports greater understanding of the role of socioeconomic factors. It also demands collective cross-sectoral action through changes in social and economic policy, as well as economic frameworks that move beyond an exclusive focus on economic growth to embrace collective and societal wellbeing.

The importance of socioeconomic factors for mental health

'Economics is the mother tongue of public policy, the language of public life, and the mindset that shapes society' (Raworth, 2017 , p. 6)

Growing evidence connects economic inequality and poor mental health (Friedli, 2009 ; Pickett and Wilkinson, 2010 ; Platt et al., 2017 ). Experience of socioeconomic disadvantage, including unemployment, low income, poverty, debt and poor housing, is consistently associated with poorer mental health (Silva et al., 2016 ; Elliott, 2016 ; Platt et al., 2017 ; Friedli, 2009 , Rogers and Pilgrim, 2010 ). Mental health problems are particularly prominent amongst marginalised groups experiencing social exclusion, discrimination and trauma, leading to compound vulnerability (Rafferty et al., 2015 ). Greater inequality within societies is associated with greater prevalence of mental illness (Wilkinson and Pickett, 2009 ; Pickett and Wilkinson, 2010 ), and economic recessions have had devastating impacts on population mental health (Platt et al., 2017 ; Wahlbeck and McDaid, 2012 ). At a global level, mental health and substance use disorders account for between one fifth and almost one third of Years Lived with Disability (Whiteford et al., 2013 ; Vigo et al., 2016 ). At the same time there is increasing interest in how to promote positive mental health at a societal level (Friedli, 2009 ; Rogers and Pilgrim, 2010 ; Hanlon and Carlisle, 2013 ).

However, the dominance of medical, psychiatric and psychological perspectives on mental health from the 1970s onwards has distracted from socioeconomic factors (Smith, 2016b ; Shim et al., 2014 ). Drawing on contemporary research on the social determinants of mental health, with particular reference to Europe and the U.S., this paper argues that a sharper focus on socioeconomic factors is required in research and policy to address inequalities in mental health.

Contemporary research on socioeconomic determinants of mental health

'Today, in the wake of the global economic slowdown, rising rates of mental illness and disaffection with psychopharmacology, the idea that there are social determinants of mental health is taking root once more'. (Smith, 2016b , p. 9)

There is growing interest across disciplines in understanding and addressing the social determinants of mental health (Friedli, 2009 ; Fisher and Baum, 2010 ; Bowen and Walton, 2015 ; Kinderman, 2016 ; Compton and Shim, 2015 ; Smith, 2016b ; Silva et al., 2016 ). This sits alongside increased attention to public mental health, and the promotion of positive societal well-being (Wahlbeck, 2015 ; Rogers and Pilgrim, 2010 ; Hanlon and Carlisle, 2013 ). The role of psychosocial factors and chronic stress has also been emphasised in understanding health inequalities (Fisher and Baum, 2010 ; Wilkinson and Pickett, 2017 ). Furthermore, stigma (a ubiquitous component of mental health difficulties), has been recognised as a fundamental cause of health inequalities (Hatzenbuehler et al., 2013 ).

However, within the broad literature on the social determinants of mental health, to what extent are socio-economic factors considered? There is consistent evidence supporting the link between socioeconomic inequality in terms of income, employment, and neighbourhood environments and poorer mental health outcomes (Silva et al., 2016 ). At an ecological level, a significant relationship has been shown between higher income inequality (as measured by the Gini coefficient) and higher incidence rates of schizophrenia (Burns et al., 2014 ). In addition, the connection between experience of socioeconomic disadvantage and increased risk of suicidal behaviour has also been established (Platt et al., 2017 ). Furthermore, the association between educational inequalities and mental health outcomes may be attenuated by controlling for employment status, indicating the importance of employment for mental health (Katikireddi et al., 2016 ). At a community level, low socioeconomic status may lead to greater concerns about neighbourhood safety, and decrease the amount of physical activity in the community, with consequent impacts on mental health (Meyer et al., 2014 ). A focus on socioeconomic factors may also link with ideas of social capital or community efficacy, measures of trust and commitment by residents to a neighbourhood (Platt et al., 2017 ), which have been linked to rates of depression, suicide, and internalising behaviours (Schmidt et al., 2014 ).

Many argue for a renewed focus on social justice, advocating for the significance of socioeconomic factors for mental health (Friedli, 2009 ; Rogers and Pilgrim, 2010 ). The impact of material and economic conditions and consumerism on population wellbeing is also recognised (Rogers and Pilgrim, 2010 ; Friedli, 2009 ). From a U.S. perspective, Jones et al. ( 2009 ) offer a theoretical framework to identify the social determinants of inequity shaped by systems of power and the distribution of resources, including an economic system that creates class structures and dimensions of opportunity (Jones et al., 2009 ). In addition, disparities in education and income play a major role in understanding racial difference in health and mental health (Williams et al., 1997 ). Krieger et al. ( 1997 ) argue that social class, at the household and community level, predicts inequalities in health (Krieger et al., 1997 ), and the role of economic inequality, poverty, and deprivation is implicated in poor mental health in the United States (Compton and Shim, 2015 ; Manseau, 2015 ).

Despite this, in comparison with biomedical, neuropsychiatric and psychological literature, the social determinants of mental health are strikingly understudied (Shim et al., 2014 ). In Europe, research on the prevention of poor mental health has received a comparatively low level of investment (Wykes et al., 2015 ). In the United States, funding of prevention constitutes a notoriously small percentage of overall healthcare expenditures (Miller et al., 2012 ). Yet the economic cost of treatment and lost productivity related to mental health and substance use disorder is well documented. While the National Institute for Mental Health named prevention as a core objective in its strategic plan for research (National Institute for Mental Health, 2015 ), there is not a clear picture of the scope and scale of investment in mental health prevention across government and philanthropy. It is likely there has been even less investment in research on the social determinants of mental health, and socioeconomic factors in particular. Thus, there is a need for greater research capacity (Wahlbeck and McDaid, 2012 ).

Moving from evidence to action: policy, communities and practice

'levels of mental distress among communities need to be understood less in terms of individual pathology and more as a response to relative deprivation and social injustice' (Friedli, 2009 , p.III)

However, it is not only further evidence on the link between economic inequality and mental health that is required, but also action to address it (Smith, 2016b ). This may require a shift from addressing individuals’ psychological states to a focus on social justice and broader economic conditions. Current attempts to move this direction include action in policy, communities and service provision.

In policy, this agenda was advanced by a World Health Organisation report in 2014, which highlighted the social determinants of mental health at an international level (World Health Organization, 2014 ). In Europe, the Joint Action on Mental Health has championed a focus on ‘Mental Health in All Policies’, which promotes action in non-health policy areas including employment and welfare (EU Directorate General for Health and Food Safety, 2015 ). Evidence is beginning to accumulate on relevant policy actions, including labour market regulation (Katikireddi et al., 2016 ) and part-time sickness absence (EU Directorate General for Health and Food Safety, 2015 ), investment in social protection (Niedzwiedz et al., 2016 ), and protective employment policies (Platt et al., 2017 ). In the United States, better population health outcomes have also been found in states with more progressive policies such as minimum wage and corporate tax rates (Rigby and Hatch, 2016 ). It has also been raised that a Universal Basic Income might positively impact on population mental health (Smith, 2016b ). Whilst there is evidence for interventions which can lessen the impact of poverty and inequality on mental health, including interventions aimed at the individual or family level (e.g., parenting interventions), evidence is more limited on community interventions or on cross-sectoral action on policies (Wahlbeck et al., 2017 ).

At a community level, the expansion of the Community Schools model in the U.S., which provides children in socioeconomically disadvantaged areas, with access to health services (medical, dental, vision and counselling services), brings more holistic attention to the education and healthy development of children (Oakes and Daniel, 2017 ). Education policies that recognise structural inequalities show promise to close the economic and achievement gap. Additionally, New York City has launched Thrive NYC, a comprehensive city-based mental health plan to reduce stigma, intervene early, and improve access to services (NYC Thrive, 2016 ). Encouraging partnership and reducing silos, a major component of the initiative, has linked community based organisations serving the most socially and economically disadvantaged populations with mental health providers to increase access to mental health and substance use services (Chapman et al., 2017 ). Furthermore, efforts at a community level which promote social capital are promoted as a buffer against the impact of socioeconomic factors (Wahlbeck and McDaid, 2012 ).

At the level of service provision, there are moves to increase professional awareness and advocacy on the social determinants of mental health (Compton and Shim, 2015 , Shim et al., 2014 ). This may include a focus on social justice and socioeconomic factors in therapeutic work. Kinderman argues 'practical help to resolve real-world issues such as debt, employment issues, housing problems and domestic violence' may be important roles for clinicians (Kinderman, 2016 , p. 4). Shim et al. ( 2014 ) also suggest that mental health professionals have an advocacy role to influence public policies that impact on mental health (Shim et al., 2014 ). Bowen and Walton argue that there is a role for social workers in addressing racial and ethnic disparities in mental health (Bowen and Walton, 2015 ). One relevant example from the U.K. is the work of Psychologists Against Austerity, who have campaigned on the mental health impact of welfare policies (McGrath et al., 2016 ).

Trying to focus ‘upstream’: barriers to action on socioeconomic factors

'We are failing on health equity because we are failing on equity' (Braveman, 2012 , p. 515)

A distinction is often made between 'upstream societal influences' (which can include living and working conditions and wider societal structures) and 'downstream risk factors' (which include behaviours such as smoking or drinking as well as biological risk factors) (Graham, 2009 , p. 472). To effectively take action on socioeconomic factors and mental health, there is a need for awareness of what might pull research and policy ‘downstream’ (Douglas, 2016 ; Graham, 2009 ). These barriers might include the dominance of the current economic paradigm, a focus on psychological or community resilience, ignoring factors like structural racism, or the challenges of mental health care provision.

In health inequalities research it is argued that an exclusive focus on health may over-medicalise the issue, veiling the fundamental problem of social inequality (Lynch, 2017 ; Douglas, 2016 ). It is stated that efforts should include awareness of the socioeconomic and political contexts which generate health inequalities, particularly the influence of neoliberalism (Smith et al., 2016a ; Collins et al., 2016 ) Such arguments are equally salient to mental health. However, focusing ‘upstream’ presents challenges given that the dominant neoliberal paradigm 'actively embraces inequality' (Collins et al., 2016 , p. 129). This may point to confronting the current inequitable economic paradigm and considering alternatives to economic growth that incorporate broader social and environmental concerns (Fioramonti, 2016 ; Raworth, 2017 ). A sharper focus on fundamental inequalities, and the economic system which underpins them, may be critical to addressing the ‘upstream’ influences on mental health.

It has also been argued that it may be problematic to focus on psychological or community assets and strengths, and social capital, as this may mask a focus on socioeconomic factors, which are fundamental causes of distress (Friedli, 2016; Rogers and Pilgrim, 2010 ; Knifton, 2015 ). Indeed, Friedli argues: 'Choosing psycho -analysis over economic analysis has serious consequences for how public health explains and responds to issues of social justice' (Friedli, 2016 , p. 216, original emphasis). This argument may be particularly relevant for mental health, where psychological conceptualisations may predominate. Within a neoliberal policy framework, there is the danger of endorsing individualistic conceptualisations of complex social and economic problems, where the predominant biomedical model has often resulted in a systematic neglect of the impact of social and structural barriers experienced by people with poor mental health (Bayetti et al., 2016 ; Friedli, 2016 ). Thus, whilst the relevance of psychosocial factors is recognised, it is important to increase the salience of social and economic inequalities which generate inequalities in mental health at a population level.

Furthermore, it is critical to consider race and ethnicity (Lynch and Perera, 2017 ). While racism has been identified as a social determinant of health, there is a significant lack of research or policy to address it (Bailey et al., 2017 ; Rafferty et al., 2015 ). Advancing policies to tackle structural racism may have significant implications for population mental health. Despite having distinct healthcare systems and ideologies on healthcare access, both the U.S. and U.K. have significant health inequalities by race and ethnicity (Bailey et al., 2017 ; Department of Health, 2009 ). Research on mental health and racial discrimination has largely considered interpersonal discrimination, not structural racism and the link to inequalities (Bailey et al., 2017 ). While increased funding and resources for mental health services and prevention is needed, greater attention must be given to addressing structural racism that leads to inequalities in education, employment, and mental health.

Finally, the need to ensure adequate mental health care provision is a pressing concern in both Europe and the U.S. Indeed, many OECD countries face ongoing challenges regarding adequate levels of resourcing for mental health services (Wahlbeck and McDaid, 2012 ). Current healthcare policy debates in the U.S. threaten progress in increasing the number of insured individuals as well as what services they can receive. Current debate, focused on insurance access and eligibility, is troublingly void of a focus on prevention or addressing social determinants and structural racism. In fact, while mental health care access improved following implementation of the Affordable Care Act, there was no progress in reducing racial and ethnic disparities (Creedon and Le Cook, 2016 ). While advocates and researchers are pulled toward policy and legislative fights over healthcare provision, larger macro issues impacting health and mental health, i.e. social determinants, are lost. Negotiating space for dialogue on the importance of prevention, alongside service provision, will be crucial.

Conclusions: taking collective action

Smith ( 2016b ) argues that a focus on socioeconomic factors and mental health is not new, but had previously gained ground in the early 20th century (Smith, 2016b ). As a renewed interest emerges in the current context, there are increasing calls for collective actions (Kinderman, 2016 ) and inter-disciplinary and inter-sectoral approaches, which re-invigorate a focus on fundamental socioeconomic inequalities and social justice (Friedli, 2009 ; Braveman, 2012 ).

Encouragingly, the growing body of research on socioeconomic factors and social determinants of health is narrowing in on mental health. Diagnosing problems, however, is not enough. Evidence on policy actions and a collective appreciation of issues that prevent upstream approaches is also needed: structural barriers including racism and discrimination, the medicalising of population mental health, access and quality of services, and ultimately the economic system itself.

To advance upstream approaches will require an inter-disciplinary research vision which extends beyond biomedical, neuropsychiatric and psychological models of mental health, and which supports greater understanding of the role of socioeconomic factors and economics. It will necessitate bold cross-sectoral policy action including changes to wider social and economic policies such as social protection, taxation, employment and housing policy, as well as health policy. Given the ubiquity and influence of economics, this agenda should be supported by the advancement of paradigms that move beyond an exclusive focus on economic growth (Raworth, 2017 ; Fioramonti, 2016 ), and which appreciate the importance of collective and societal wellbeing (Knifton, 2015 ).

Population mental health is intimately connected to societal economic conditions. The (poor) mental health of modern societies offers a stark indication of the consequences of not taking action: 'economic growth at the cost of social recession' (Friedli, 2009 , p. IV). Socioeconomic inequality may be 'the enemy between us' (Wilkinson and Pickett, 2017 , p. 11), increasing status competition, undermining the quality of social relations, increasing stress and impacting on health, mental health, and wellbeing. In response to this, there is a need to build an economic system that tackles these inequalities in mental health.

Bailey ZD, Krieger N, Agenor M, Graves J et al. (2017) Structural racism and health inequities in the USA: evidence and interventions. Lancet 389:1453–1463

Article   PubMed   Google Scholar  

Bayetti C, Jadhavb S, Jainc S (2016) The Re-covering self: a critique of the recovery-based approach in India’s mental health care. Disabil Glob South 3:889–909

Google Scholar  

Bowen EA, Walton QL (2015) Disparities and the social determinants of mental health and addictions: opportunities for a multifaceted social work response. Health Soc Work 40:E59–E65

Article   Google Scholar  

Braveman P (2012) We are failing on health equity because we are failing on equity. Aust N Z J Public Health 36:515–515

Burns JK, Tomita A, Kapadia AS (2014) Income inequality and schizophrenia: Increased schizophrenia incidence in countries with high levels of income inequality. Int J Social Psychiatr 60:185–196

Chapman E, Chung H, Pincus HA (2017) Using a continuum-based framework for behavioral health integration into primary care in New York state. Psychiatr Serv 68:756–758

Collins C, McCartney G, Garnham L (2016) Neoliberalism and health inequalities. In: Smith KE, Hill S, Bambra C (eds) Health inequalities: critical perspectives. Oxford University Press, Oxford

Compton MT, Shim RS (2015) Social determinants of mental health. American Psychiatric Publishing, Washington

Creedon TB, Le Cook B (2016) Access to mental health care increased but not for substance use, while disparities remain. Health Aff 35:1017–1021

Department of Health (2009) Tackling health inequalities: 10 years on—a review of developments in tackling health inequalities in England over the last 10 years. Department of Health, London

Douglas M (2016) Beyond ‘health’: why don’t we tackle the cause of health inequalities? In: Smith KE, Hill S, Bambra C (eds) Health inequalities: critical perspectives. Oxford University Press, Oxford

EU Directorate General for Health and Food Safety (2015) Joint action on mental health and well-being. Mental Health in all Policies—situation analysis and recommendations for action. http://www.mentalhealthandwellbeing.eu/assets/docs/publications/MHiAP%20Final.pdf . Accessed 20 Jul 2017

Elliott I (2016) Poverty and mental health: A review to inform the Joseph Rowntree Foundation’s Anti-Poverty Strategy. Mental Health Foundation, London

Fioramonti L (2016) A post-GDP world? Rethinking international politics in the 21(st) century. Glob Policy 7:15–24

Fisher M, Baum F (2010) The social determinants of mental health: implications for research and health promotion. Aust NZ J Psychiatr 44:1057–1063

Friedli L (2009) Mental health, resilience and inequalities. World Health Organization, Copenhagen

Friedli L (2016) The politics of tackling inequalities: The rise of psychological fundamentalism in public health and welfare reform. In: Smith KE, Hill S, Bambra C (eds) Health inequalities: critical perspectives. Oxford University Press, Oxford

Graham H (2009) Health inequalities, social determinants and public health policy. Policy & Polit 37:463–479

Hanlon P, Carlisle S (2013) Positive mental health and wellbeing: connecting individual, social and global levels of wellbeing. In: Knifton L, Quinn N (eds) Public mental health: global perspectives. Open University Press, Maidenhead

Hatzenbuehler ML, Phelan JC, Link BG (2013) Stigma as a fundamental cause of population health inequalities. Am J Public Health 103:813–821

Article   PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Jones CP, J C, Perry GS, Barclay G, Jones CA (2009) Addressing the social determinants of children’s health: a cliff analogy. J Health Care Poor Under 20:1–12

Katikireddi SV, Niedzwiedz CL, Popham F (2016) Employment status and income as potential mediators of educational inequalities in population mental health. Eur J Public Health 26:814–816

Kinderman P (2016) Knots and black holes: why we are all prone to madness and what we can do about it. Palgrave Commun 2:16074. https://doi.org/10.1057/palcomms.2016.74

Knifton L (2015) Collective wellbeing in public mental health. Perspect Public Health 135:24–26

Krieger N, Williams DR, Moss NE (1997) Measuring social class in US public health research: concepts, methodologies, and guidelines. Annu Rev Public Health 18:341–378

Article   CAS   PubMed   Google Scholar  

Lynch J (2017) Reframing inequality? The health inequalities turn as a dangerous frame shift J Public Health 39:1–8

Lynch JF, Perera IM (2017) Framing Health Equity: US health disparities in comparative perspective J Health Polit Policy Law 42:803–839

Manseau MW (2015) Economic inequality, poverty and neighbourhood deprivation. In: Compton MT, Shim RS (eds) The social determinants of mental health. American Psychiatric Publishing, Washington

McGrath L, Griffin V, Mundy E (2016) The Psychological Impact of Austerity. A briefing paper. Educational Psychology Research and Practice 2:46–57

Meyer OL, Castro-Schilo L, Aguilar-Gaxiola S (2014) Determinants of mental health and self-rated health: a model of socioeconomic status, neighborhood safety, and physical activity. Am J Public Health 104:1734–1741

Miller G, Roehrig C, Hughes-Cromwick P, Turner A (2012) What is currently spent on prevention as compared to treatment?. In: Faust H, M P (eds) Prevention vs. treatment: what’s the right balance?. Oxford University Press, New York

National Institute of Mental Health (NIOM) (2015) Strategic objective 3. https://www.nimh.nih.gov/about/strategic-planning-reports/strategic-objective-3.shtml

Niedzwiedz CL, Mitchell RJ, Shortt NK, Pearce JR (2016) Social protection spending and inequalities in depressive symptoms across Europe. Soc Psychiatry Psychiatr Epidemiol 51:1005–1014

NYC Thrive (2016) Thrive NYC. A roadmap for mental health for all. https://thrivenyc.cityofnewyork.us/wp-content/uploads/2017/02/ThriveNYC.pdf

Oakes J, Maier A, Daniel J (2017) Community schools: an evidence-based strategy for equitable school improvement. National Education Policy Center, Boulder, CO

Pickett KE, Wilkinson RG (2010) Inequality: an underacknowledged source of mental illness and distress. Br J Psychiatr 197:426–428

Platt S, Stace S, Morrissey J (eds) (2017) Dying From Inequality: Socioeconomic Distadvantage and Suicidal Behaviour. Samaritans, London

Rafferty JA, Abelson JM, Bryant K, Jackson JS (2015) Discrimination. In: Compton MT, Shim RS (ed) The Social Determinants of Mental Health. American Psychiatric Publishing, Washington

Raworth K (2017) Doughnut economics. Seven ways to think like a 21st-century economist. Random House Business Books, London

Rigby E, Hatch ME (2016) Incorporating economic policy into a ‘health-in-all-policies’ agenda. Health Aff 35:2044–2052

Rogers A, Pilgrim D (2010) A sociology of mental health and illness. Open University Press, Maidenhead

Schmidt NM, Tchetgen Tchetgen EJ, Ehntholt A, Almeida J, Nguyen QC, Molnar BE, Azrael D, Osypuk TL (2014) Does neighborhood collective efficacy for families change over time? The Boston Neighborhood Survey. J Commun Psychol 42:61–79

Shim R, Koplan C, Langheim FJP, Manseau MW et al. (2014) The social determinants of mental health: an overview and call to action. Psychiatr Ann 44:22–26

Silva M, Loureiro A, Cardoso G (2016) Social determinants of mental health: a review of the evidence. Eur J Psychiatry 30:259–292

Smith KE, Hill S, Bambra C (eds) (2016a) Conclusion—where next for advocates, researchers, and policymakers trying to tackle health inequalities? In: Health inequalities. Critical perspectives. Oxford University Press, Oxford

Smith M (2016b) A fine balance: individualism, society and the prevention of mental illness in the United States, 1945–1968. Palgrave Commun 2. https://doi.org/10.1057/palcomms.2016.24

Vigo D, Thornicroft G, Atun R (2016) Estimating the true global burden of mental illness. Lancet Psychiatr 3:171–178

Wahlbeck K (2015) Public mental health: the time is ripe for translation of evidence into practice. World Psychiatr 14:36–42

Wahlbeck K, Cresswell-Smith J, Haaramo P, Parkkonen J (2017) Interventions to mitigate the effects of poverty and inequality on mental health. Soc Psychiatr Psychiatr Epidemiol 52:505–514

Wahlbeck K, McDaid D (2012) Actions to alleviate the mental health impact of the economic crisis. World Psychiatr 11:139–145

Whiteford HA, Degenhardt L, Rehm J, Baxter AJ et al. (2013) Global burden of disease attributable to mental and substance use disorders: findings from the Global Burden of Disease Study 2010. Lancet 382:1575–1586

Wilkinson R, Pickett K (2009) The Spirit level. Why equality is better for everyone. Penguin Books, London

Wilkinson RG, Pickett KE (2017) The enemy between us: The psychological and social costs of inequality. Eur J Soc Psychol 47:11–24

Williams DR, Y Y, Jackson JS, Anderson NB (1997) Racial differences in physical and mental health: Socio-economic status, stress and discrimination. J Health Psychol 2:335–351

World Health Organization and Calouste Gulbenkian Foundation (WHOCG) (2014) Social determinants of mental health. World Health Organization, Geneva

Wykes T, Haro JM, Belli SR, Obradors-Tarrago C et al. (2015) Mental health research priorities for Europe. Lancet Psychiatr 2:1036–1042

Download references

Acknowledgements

The collaboration for this paper was made possible by a European Union funded Horizon 2020 RISE project ‘Citizenship, Recovery and Inclusive Society Partnership’ ( www.crisppartnership.eu) . This project has received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme under the Marie Sklodowska-Curie grant agreement, No 690954. The views in this publication are solely the responsibility of the authors. The Commission is not responsible for any use that may be made of the information it contains.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Centre for Health Policy, University of Strathclyde, Glasgow, UK

Anna Macintyre & Neil Quinn

Brown School of Social Work at Washington University; Envolve Center for Health Behavior Change, St. Louis, MO, USA

Daniel Ferris

McSilver Institute for Poverty Policy and Research at New York University Silver School of Social Work, New York, NY, USA

Briana Gonçalves

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anna Macintyre .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The authors declare no competing financial interests.

Additional information

Publisher's note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Macintyre, A., Ferris, D., Gonçalves, B. et al. What has economics got to do with it? The impact of socioeconomic factors on mental health and the case for collective action. Palgrave Commun 4 , 10 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-018-0063-2

Download citation

Received : 01 November 2017

Accepted : 19 December 2017

Published : 30 January 2018

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-018-0063-2

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

This article is cited by

Longitudinal microstructural changes in 18 amygdala nuclei resonate with cortical circuits and phenomics.

  • Karam Ghanem
  • Karin Saltoun
  • Danilo Bzdok

Communications Biology (2024)

Sociocultural determinants of psychological distress and coping among South Asian individuals with chronic illness

  • Ahtisham Younas
  • Faisal Aziz

Discover Psychology (2024)

Emotional and Financial Stressors in New York City During the COVID-19 Pandemic: A Consecutive Cross-Sectional Analysis

  • David J. Heller
  • Devin Madden
  • Nita Vangeepuram

Journal of Racial and Ethnic Health Disparities (2024)

Period poverty and mental health in a representative sample of young women in Barcelona, Spain

  • Marga Marí-Klose
  • Albert Julià
  • Pedro Gallo

BMC Women's Health (2023)

Longitudinal mediating effect of social capital on the relationship between public housing and mental health: evidence from South Korea

  • In Kwon Park

Journal of Housing and the Built Environment (2023)

Quick links

  • Explore articles by subject
  • Guide to authors
  • Editorial policies

case study on economic inequality

Information

  • Author Services

Initiatives

You are accessing a machine-readable page. In order to be human-readable, please install an RSS reader.

All articles published by MDPI are made immediately available worldwide under an open access license. No special permission is required to reuse all or part of the article published by MDPI, including figures and tables. For articles published under an open access Creative Common CC BY license, any part of the article may be reused without permission provided that the original article is clearly cited. For more information, please refer to https://www.mdpi.com/openaccess .

Feature papers represent the most advanced research with significant potential for high impact in the field. A Feature Paper should be a substantial original Article that involves several techniques or approaches, provides an outlook for future research directions and describes possible research applications.

Feature papers are submitted upon individual invitation or recommendation by the scientific editors and must receive positive feedback from the reviewers.

Editor’s Choice articles are based on recommendations by the scientific editors of MDPI journals from around the world. Editors select a small number of articles recently published in the journal that they believe will be particularly interesting to readers, or important in the respective research area. The aim is to provide a snapshot of some of the most exciting work published in the various research areas of the journal.

Original Submission Date Received: .

  • Active Journals
  • Find a Journal
  • Proceedings Series
  • For Authors
  • For Reviewers
  • For Editors
  • For Librarians
  • For Publishers
  • For Societies
  • For Conference Organizers
  • Open Access Policy
  • Institutional Open Access Program
  • Special Issues Guidelines
  • Editorial Process
  • Research and Publication Ethics
  • Article Processing Charges
  • Testimonials
  • Preprints.org
  • SciProfiles
  • Encyclopedia

socsci-logo

Article Menu

  • Subscribe SciFeed
  • Recommended Articles
  • Google Scholar
  • on Google Scholar
  • Table of Contents

Find support for a specific problem in the support section of our website.

Please let us know what you think of our products and services.

Visit our dedicated information section to learn more about MDPI.

JSmol Viewer

Is economic inequality really a problem a review of the arguments.

case study on economic inequality

1. Introduction

2. some basic facts about inequality.

But from the moment one man needed the help of another, as soon as it was thought to be useful for a single person to have provisions for two, equality disappeared, property was introduced, labor became necessary, and vast forests were changed into smiling fields which had to be watered with the sweat of men, and in which slavery and misery were soon seen to germinate and grow with the crops.... Metallurgy and agriculture were the two arts whose invention produced this great revolution. ( Rousseau [1753] 2011, p. 76 )

3. Arguments that Economic Inequality Is Not a Threat to Social Justice or Economic Stability

4. arguments that inequality in itself is a grave social problem, 4.1. the intrinsic value of greater equality: distributive justice.

The economic framework that each society has—its laws, institutions, policies, etc.—results in different distributions of economic benefits and burdens across members of the society. These economic frameworks are the result of human political processes and they constantly change both across societies and within societies over time... Arguments about which frameworks and/or resulting distributions are morally preferable constitute the topic of distributive justice.

4.2. The Instrumental Value of Reducing Inequality

4.2.1. the economic effects of inequality, 4.2.2. inequality, politics, and democracy, 4.2.3. behavioral changes and health disparities, 4.2.4. inequality and social and environmental ills.

The rich are disproportionate contributors to the carbon emissions that power climate change. It is cruel and perverse, therefore, that the costs of warming should be disproportionately borne by the poor. And it is both insult and injury that the wealthy are more mobile in the face of climate-induced hardship, and more effective at limiting the mobility of others. The strains this injustice places on the social fabric might well lead to woes more damaging than rising temperatures themselves. (p. 66)

5. Conclusions

Conflicts of interest.

  • Acemoglu, Daron, and James Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty . New York: Crown Business, Random House. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Aguiar, Mark, and Mark Bils. 2015. Has Consumption Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality? American Economic Review 105: 2725–56. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Allingham, Michael. 2014. Distributive Justice . New York: Routledge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Andersson, Krister, and Arun Agrawal. 2011. Inequalities, Institutions, and Forest Commons. Global Environmental Change 21: 866–75. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Armour, Philip. 2014. How the Top’s Share of Income Changes with Comprehensive Measurements. In Income Inequality in America: Fact and Fiction . Edited by Diana Furchtgott-Roth. New York: Manhattan Institute. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Armstrong, Chris. 2012. Global Distributive Justice: An Introduction . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Atkinson, Anthony B. 2015. Inequality: What Can Be Done? Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Attanasio, Orazio, and Luigi Pistaferri. 2016. Consumption Inequality. Journal of Economic Perspectives 30: 1–27. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Attanasio, Orazio, Erik Hurst, and Luigi Pistaferri. 2012. The Evolution of Income, Consumption, and Leisure Inequality in the US, 1980–2010. Working Paper 17982. Cambridge, MA, USA: National Bureau of Economic Research. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Autor, David H. 2014. Skills, Education, and the Rise of Earnings Inequality among the ‘Other 99%’. Science 344: 843–51. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ] [ PubMed ]
  • Azerrad, David, and Rea S. Hederman. 2012. Defending the Dream: Why Income Inequality Doesn’t Threaten Opportunity . Washington: Heritage Foundation. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Baek, Jungho, and Guankerwon Gweisah. 2013. Does Income Inequality Harm the Environment? Empirical Evidence from the United States. Energy Policy 62: 1434–37. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Becker, Gary S., and Kevin M. Murphy. 2007. The Upside of Income Inequality. The American (Journal of the American Enterprise Institute) 1: 20. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bernstein, Jared. 2013. The Impact of Inequality on Growth . Washington: Center for American Progress, Available online: https://www.americanprogress.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/12/BerensteinInequality.pdf (accessed on 28 August 2017).
  • Bischoff, Kendra. 2016. Geography of Economic Inequality. In Delivering Equitable Growth: Strategies for the Next Administration . Washington: Washington Center for Equitable Growth. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Boix, Carles. 2015. Political Order and Inequality: Their Foundations and Their Consequences for Human Welfare . New York: Cambridge University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Boushey, Heather, Bradford DeLong, and M. Steinbaum. 2017. After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality . Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bowley, Graham. 2011. New Speed of Money, Reshaping Markets. New York Times . Available online: http://www.nytimes.com/2011/01/02/business/02speed.html?pagewanted=all (accessed on 12 October 2017).
  • Boyce, James K. 2017. Inequality and the Environment . Medford: Tufts University, Available online: https://www.peri.umass.edu/images/BoyceInequality_and_the_Environment_-_Leontief_lecture.pdf (accessed on 5 October 2017).
  • Brückner, Markus, and Daniel Lederman. 2015. Effects of Income Inequality on Aggregate Output . Washington: World Bank. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Brunori, Paol, Francisco Ferreira, and Vitro Peragine. 2013. Inequality of Opportunity, Income Inequality and Economic Mobility: Some International Comparisons . Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). [ Google Scholar ]
  • Brzozowski, Matthew, Martin Gervais, Paul Klein, and Michio Suzuki. 2010. Consumption, Income, and Wealth Inequality in Canada. Review of Economic Dynamics 13: 52–75. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Butler, Daniel M. 2014. Representing the Advantaged: How Politicians Reinforce Inequality . New York: Cambridge University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Case, Anne, and Angus Deaton. 2015. Rising Morbidity and Mortality in Midlife among White Non-Hispanic Americans in the 21st Century. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 112: 15078–83. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ] [ PubMed ]
  • Census. 2017a. Table p-36. Full-Time, Year-Round All Workers by Median Income and Sex: 1955 to 2015. In Historical Income Tables: People ; Suitland: U.S. Bureau of the Census. Available online: https://www.census.gov/data/tables/time-series/demo/income-poverty/historical-income-people.html (accessed on 18 August 2017).
  • Census. 2017b. Table 2. Poverty Status of People by Family Relationships, Race, and Hispanic Origin: 1959–2016. In Historical Poverty Tables: People and Families—1959–2016 ; Suitland: U.S. Bureau of the Census. Available online: https://www.census.gov/data/tables/time-series/demo/income-poverty/historical-poverty-people.html (accessed on 17 November 2017).
  • Cingano, Federico. 2014. Trends in Income Inequality and its Impact on Economic Growth . Paris: OECD Publishing. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Collins, Chuck. 2016. Born on Third Base . West River Junction: Chelsea Green Publishing. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Conard, Edward. 2016. The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class . New York: Penguin Random House. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Deaton, Angus. 2013. The Great Escape: Health, Wealth and the Origins of Inequality . Princeton: Princeton University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Deaton, Angus. 2017. Without Governments, Would Countries have More Inequality, or Less? The Economist . Available online: https://www.economist.com/news/world-if/21724910-angus-deaton-nobel-prize-winning-economist-explores-question-intrigued-him-without (accessed on 18 August 2017).
  • Domhoff, G. William. 2017. Wealth, income, and Power. Who Rules America? Available online: http://www2.ucsc.edu/whorulesamerica/power/wealth.html (accessed on 12 September 2017).
  • Downey, Liam. 2015. Inequality, Democracy, and the Environment . New York: NYU Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Dworkin, Ronald. 2013. Justice for Hedgehogs . Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Feldman, Fred. 2016. Distributive Justice: Getting What We Deserve from Our Country . New York: Oxford University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ferreira, Francisco, and Vito Pergine. 2015. Equality of Opportunity: Theory and Evidence . Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fesseau, Maryse, and Peter van de Ven. 2014. Measuring Inequaity in Income and Consumption in a National Accounts Framework . OECD Statistics Brief No. 19. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fingerhut, Hannah. 2016. Most Americans Say U.S. Economic System is Unfair, but High-Income Republicans Disagree . Washington: Pew Research Center, Available online: http://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2016/02/10/most-americans-say-u-s-economic-system-is-unfair-but-high-income-republicans-disagree/ (accessed on 22 August 2017).
  • Fisher, Jonathan D., David S. Johnson, and Timothy Smeeding. 2013. Measuring Trends in Inequality of Individuals and Families: Income and Consumption. American Economic Review 103: 184–88. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Fleischacker, Samuel. 2004. A Short History of Distributive Justice . Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Floud, Robert, Robert W. Fogel, Bernard Harris, and Sok Chul Hong. 2011. The Changing Body: Health, Nutrition, and Human Development in the Western World since 1700 . New York: Cambridge University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Frank, Robert H. 2017. Success and Luck: Good Fortune and the Myth of Meritocracy . Princeton: Princeton University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Frankfurt, Harry G. 2015. On Inequality . Princeton: Princeton University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Furchtgoff-Roth, Diana. 2014. How Changing Demographics affect Inequality. In Income Inequality in America: Fact and Fiction . Edited by Diana Furchtgott-Roth. New York: Manhattan Institute. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Galbraith, James K. 2016. Inequality: What Everyone Needs to Know . New York: Oxford University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America . Princeton: Princeton University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Graham, Hilary. 2007. Unequal Lives: Health and Socioeconomic Inequalities . Berkshire: Open University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hassett, Kevin A., and Aparna Mathur. 2012. A New Measure of Consumption Inequality. In AEI Economic Studies . Washington: American Enterprise Institute. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hayes, Thomas J. 2011. American Attitudes toward Economic Inequality . Riverside: University of California, Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1961432 (accessed on 12 September 2017).
  • Hsiang, Solomon, Robert Kopp, Amir Jina, James Riing, Michael Delgado, Shashank Mohan, Robert Muir-Wood, Paul Wilson, Michael Oppenheimer, Kate Larson, and et al. 2017. Estimating Economic Damage from Climate Change in the United States. Science 356: 1362–69. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ] [ PubMed ]
  • Huang, Rui, Lilyan Fulginiti, and E. Wesley Peterson. 2010. Health and Growth: Causality through Education. China Agricultural Economic Review 2: 321–44. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Kerr, William R. 2011. Income Inequality and Social Preferences for Redistribution and Compensation Differentials. Working Paper 17701. Cambridge, MA, USA: National Bureau of Economic Research. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kindleberger, Charles, and Bruce Herrick. 1977. Economic Development , 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Krieger, Tim, and Daniel Meierrieks. 2016. Political Capitalism: The Interaction between Income Inequality, Economic Freedom and Democracy. European Journal of Political Economy 45: 115–32. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Krueger, Alan B. 2012. The Rise and Consequences of Inequality in the United States . Washington: Center for American Progress. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ku, Hyejin, and Timothy C. Salmon. 2009. The Incentive Effects of Inequality: An Experimental Investigation. Southern Economic Journal 79: 46–70. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Kuznets, Simon. 1955. Economic Growth and Income Inequality. American Economic Review XLV: 1–28. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Lamont, Julian, and Christi Favor. 2013. Distributive Justice. In Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy . Available online: https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/justice-distributive/ (accessed on 15 August 2017).
  • Leigh, Andrew, Christopher Jencks, and Timothy Smeeding. 2009. Health and Economic Inequality. In The Oxford Handbook of Economic Inequality . Edited by Wiemer Salverda, Brian Nolan and Timothy Smeeding. New York: Oxford University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Lewis, Oscar. 1966. La Vida: A Puerto Rican Family in the Culture of Poverty—San Juan and New York . New York: Vintage Books. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Locke, John. 1993. Two Treatises of Government . New York: Everyman Paperback. First published 1689. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Malthus, Thomas R. 2004. An Essay on the Principle of Population . New York: Oxford University Press. First published 1798. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2013. Defending the One Percent. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27: 21–34. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Mayer, Thomas H. 2015. Income Inequality: Piketty and the Neo-Marxist Revival. Cato Journal 35: 95–116. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Meyer, Bruce D., and Kames X. Sullivan. 2017. Consumption and Income Inequality in the U.S. Since the 1960s. Working Paper No. 2017-12. Chicago, IL, USA: Becker Friedman Institute, University of Chicago. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Milanovic, Branko. 2011. The Haves and the Have-Nots: A Brief and Idiosyncratic History of Global Inequality . New York: Basic Books. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Milanovic, Branko. 2016. Global Inequality: A New Approach for the Age of Globalization . Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Molander, Per. 2016. The Anatomy of Inequality . Brooklyn: Melville House Publishing. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Morris, Ian. 2015. Foragers, Farmers, and Fossil Fuels: How Human Values Evolve . Princeton: Princeton University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Newport, Frank. 2015. Americans Continue to Say U.S. Wealth Distribution is Unfair. Available online: http://news.gallup.com/poll/182987/americans-continue-say-wealth-distribution-unfair.aspx (accessed on 10 August 2017).
  • Noah, Timothy. 2013. The Great Divergence: America’s Growing Inequality Crisis and What We Can do about It . New York: Bloomsbury Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Norton, Michael I., and Dan Ariely. 2011. Building a Better America—One Wealth Quintile at a Time. Perspectives on Psychological Science 6: 9–12. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ] [ PubMed ]
  • Nozick, Robert. 1974. Anarchy, Sate and Utopia . New York: Basic Books, Inc. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Nussbaum, Martha C. 2000. Women and Human Development: The Capabilities Approach . New York: Cambridge University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • O’Leary, Naomi. 2014. Pope Francis ‘Evangelii Gaudium’ Calls for Renewal of Roman Catholic Church, Attacks ‘Idolatry of Money’. Huffington Post . Available online: http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2013/11/26/pope-francis-evangelii-gaudium_n_4342964.html (accessed on 12 October 2017).
  • Osberg, Lars, and Timothy Smeeding. 2006. ‘Fair’ Inequality? Attitudes toward Pay Differentials: The United States in Comparative Perspective. American Sociological Review 71: 450–73. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Oxfam. 2014. Working for the Few: Political Capture and Economic Inequality. Oxford Briefing Paper 178. Available online: https://www.oxfam.org/sites/www.oxfam.org/files/bp-working-for-few-political-capture-economic-inequality-200114-summ-en.pdf (accessed on 5 October 2017).
  • Page, Benjamin I., Larry M. Bartels, and Jason Seawright. 2013. Democracy and the Policy Preferences of Wealthy Americans. Perspectives on Politics 11: 51–73. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Payne, Keith. 2017. The Broken Ladder: How Inequality Affects the Way We Think, Live, and Die . New York: Viking Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Peterson, E. Wesley F. 2017. The Role of Population in Economic Growth. SAGE Open October-December: 1–15. Available online: http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/pdf/10.1177/2158244017736094 (accessed on 1 December 2017).
  • Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the 21st Century . Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Piketty, Thomas. 2015. The Economics of Inequality . Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pinker, Steven. 2011. The Better Angels of Our Nature: Why Violence Has Declined . New York: Penguin Books. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pringle, Heather. 2014. The Ancient Roots of the 1%. Science 348: 822–25. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ] [ PubMed ]
  • Pryor, Frederic L. 2012. The Impact of Income Inequality on Values and Attitudes. The Journal of Socio-Economics 41: 615–22. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Putnam, Robert D. 2015. Our Kids: The American Dream in Crisis . New York: Simon and Schuster. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice . Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Roemer, John E. 1998. Equality of Opportunity . Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rousseau, Jean-Jacques. 2011. Discourse on the Origin and Foundations of Inequality among Men . Translated and Edited by Helena Rosenblatt. New York: St. Martin’s. First published 1753. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Saez, Emmanuel. 2017. Taxing the Rich More: Preliminary Evidence from the 2013 Tax Increase. Tax Policy and the Economy 31: 71–120. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ]
  • Sandel, Michael. 2012. What Money Can’t Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets . New York: Farrar, Strauss and Giroux. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sayer, Andrew. 2016. Why We Can’t Afford the Rich . Chicago: The Policy Press and University of Chicago Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Scheidel, Walter. 2017. The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century . Princeton: Princeton University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sen, Amartya K. 1999. Development as Freedom . New York: Alfred A. Knopf. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sen, Amartya K. 2009. The Idea of Justice . Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Shin, Laura. 2014. The 85 Richest People in the World Have as Much Wealth as the 3.5 Billion Poorest. Forbes . January 23. Available online: https://www.forbes.com/sites/laurashin/2014/01/23/the-85-richest-people-in-the-world-have-as-much-wealth-as-the-3-5-billion-poorest/#6f5224d91753 (accessed on 17 August 2017).
  • Sitaraman, Ganesh. 2017. The Crisis of the Middle-Class Constitution: Why Economic Inequality Threatens Our Republic . New York: Alfred A. Knopf. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Skelton, Renee, and Vernice Miller. 2016. The Environmental Justice Movement . New York: Natural Resources Defense Council (NRDC), Available online: https://www.nrdc.org/stories/environmental-justice-movement (accessed on 12 October 2017).
  • Skidelsky, Robert, and Edward Skidelsky. 2012. How Much Is Enough? Money and the Good Life . New York: Other Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Spencer, Herbert. 1969. Social Statics . New York: Augustus M. Kelley. First published 1851. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2013. The Price of Inequality: How Today’s Divided Society Endangers our Future . New York: W. W. Norton and Company. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2016. The Great Divide: Unequal Societies and What We Can Do About Them . New York: W. W. Norton & Company. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Stone, Chad, Danilo Trisi, Arloc Sherman, and Emily Horton. 2016. A Guide to Statistics on Historical Trends in Income Inequality. In Policy Futures . Washington: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. [ Google Scholar ]
  • The Economist. Climate Change and Inequality. Available online: https://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21725009-rich-pollute-poor-suffer-climate-change-and-inequality (accessed on 27 September 2017).
  • The Maddison-Project. 2013. Maddison Project Database. Groningen Growth and Development Center 2013 version. Available online: http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/maddison-project/home.htm (accessed on 8 June 2017).
  • Therborn, Goran. 2013. The Killing Fields of Inequality . Malden: Polity Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Thompson, Michael J. 2012. The Politics of Inequality: A Political History of the Idea of Economic Inequality in America . New York: Columbia University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Thompson, Jeffrey, and Elias Leight. 2011. Searching for the Supposed Benefits of Higher Inequality: Impacts of Rising Top Shares on Standard of Living of Low and Middle-Income Families. Working Paper 258. Amherst, MA, USA: Political Economy Research Institute, University of Massachusetts-Amherst. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Todarao, Michael, and Stephen Smith. 2012. Economic Development , 11th ed. New York: Addison-Wesley. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Troutt, David D. 2013. The Price of Paradise: The Costs of Inequality and a Vision for a More Equitable America . New York: New York University Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Underwood, Emily. 2014. Can Disparities Be Deadly? Controversial Research Explores Whether Living in an Unequal Society Can Make People Sick. Science 344: 829–31. [ Google Scholar ] [ CrossRef ] [ PubMed ]
  • Watkins, Don, and Yaron Brook. 2016. Equal is Unfair: America’s Misguided Fight against Income Inequality . New York: St. Martin’s Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Watson, William. 2015. The Inequality Trap: Fighting Capitalism Instead of Poverty . Toronto: University of Toronto Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Wike, Richard. 2014. With 41% of Global Wealth in the Hands of Less than 1%, Elites and Citizens Agree Inequality is a Top Priority . Washington: Pew Research Center, Available online: http://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2014/11/08/with-41-of-global-wealth-in-the-hands-of-less-than-1-elites-and-citizens-agree-inequality-is-a-top-priority/ (accessed on 27 September 2017).
  • Wilkinson, Will. 2009. Thinking Clearly about Economic Inequality. In Policy Analysis . Washington: Cato Institute. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Wilkinson, Richard, and Kate Pickett. 2009. The Spirit Level: Why Greater Equality Makes Stronger Societies . New York: Bloomsbury Press. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Winship, Scott. 2014. Should we Care about Income Inequality? In Income Inequality in America: Fact and Fiction . Edited by Diana Furchtgott-Roth. New York: Manhattan Institute. [ Google Scholar ]
  • World Bank. 2017. World Development Indicators Databank. Available online: http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=world-development-indicators (accessed on 16 October 2017).
YearLMSSAEAPSALA
19628.488.874.605.5423.91
19658.718.284.135.6823.27
19687.367.113.994.2621.35
19717.217.294.063.9420.69
19747.097.203.723.2521.80
19777.227.163.532.8822.05
19806.516.662.902.6520.77
19836.636.083.182.9519.40
19865.724.233.132.6215.33
19894.283.492.252.1012.00
19924.162.673.771.6413.65
19954.112.202.891.5414.43
19984.522.163.371.6816.46
20014.391.903.811.7314.49
20044.622.094.521.8712.24
20076.152.716.022.3115.48
20108.313.229.482.9119.48
201310.403.8713.243.3522.57
201610.843.6716.273.9419.38
Country. PeriodReal GDP GrowthPopulation GrowthReal Per Capita GDP GrowthGini Coefficient, Most Recent Year *
Norway, 1913–20103.220.712.510.253
France, 1913–20102.340.471.870.306
Korea, 1913–20105.511.593.920.302
Mexico, 1913–20103.672.131.540.457
United States, 1913–20102.991.191.800.401
Norway, 1960–20153.130.672.46
France, 1960–20152.750.652.10
Korea, 1960–20156.961.285.68
Mexico, 1960–20153.902.181.72
United States, 1960–20153.041.032.01
Norway, 1990–20152.440.851.59
France, 1990–20151.480.530.95
Korea, 1990–20154.840.664.18
Mexico, 1990–20152.681.581.10
United States, 1990–20152.380.981.40

Share and Cite

Peterson, E.W.F. Is Economic Inequality Really a Problem? A Review of the Arguments. Soc. Sci. 2017 , 6 , 147. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci6040147

Peterson EWF. Is Economic Inequality Really a Problem? A Review of the Arguments. Social Sciences . 2017; 6(4):147. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci6040147

Peterson, E. Wesley F. 2017. "Is Economic Inequality Really a Problem? A Review of the Arguments" Social Sciences 6, no. 4: 147. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci6040147

Article Metrics

Article access statistics, further information, mdpi initiatives, follow mdpi.

MDPI

Subscribe to receive issue release notifications and newsletters from MDPI journals

IMAGES

  1. (PDF) On Data: A Case Study of the Evolution of Income Inequality

    case study on economic inequality

  2. (PDF) The Impact of Income Inequality On Economic Growth: A Case Study

    case study on economic inequality

  3. Solved Case Study: Inequality, Poverty and Wealth A study

    case study on economic inequality

  4. (PDF) Impact of Economic Globalization on Income Inequality: Developed

    case study on economic inequality

  5. a. Economic Change and Social Inequality: Case Study ... / a-economic

    case study on economic inequality

  6. Case Study 5 Institutions, Inequality, and Incomes Ghana and Côte d

    case study on economic inequality

VIDEO

  1. Racial inequality has widened, why is this the case? Has the Civil Rights movement failed?

  2. Prof. Alan Krueger: Why excessive inequality is economically inefficient

  3. CASE STUDY DIGEST PAPER 6D ECONOMIC LAW

  4. Unaccompanied Minors at the Border

  5. Inequality Tricks Definitely False case #shorts #studysmart #reasoning

  6. How to study Economic law Case study

COMMENTS

  1. On the Impact of Inequality on Growth, Human Development, and

    Relatedly, empirical work suggests that economic inequality harms support for democracy (e.g., Andersen 2012; Krieckhaus et al. 2014) and political inequality (e.g., ... which in the case of children can lead to feeling less willing to study or stay in school and in the case of parents can cause stress and alienation. The second suggests that ...

  2. Rising inequality affecting more than two-thirds of the globe, but it's

    The World Social Report 2020, published by the UN Department of Economic and Social Affairs (DESA), shows that income inequality has increased in most developed countries, and some middle-income countries - including China, which has the world's fastest growing economy.. The challenges are underscored by UN chief António Guterres in the foreword, in which he states that the world is ...

  3. The Roots of Economic Inequality

    The Roots of Economic Inequality. A new study shows that deeply ingrained social behaviors play a role in perpetuating economic inequality. Yale SOM's Michael Kraus, one of the authors of the study, says we all need to mind the widening gap between rich and poor. The United States is divided by wealth and social class, and the gap is widening.

  4. Trends in U.S. income and wealth inequality

    Why economic inequality matters. The rise in economic inequality in the U.S. is tied to several factors. These include, in no particular order, technological change, globalization, the decline of unions and the eroding value of the minimum wage.Whatever the causes, the uninterrupted increase in inequality since 1980 has caused concern among members of the public, researchers, policymakers and ...

  5. Signs of Social Class: The Experience of Economic Inequality in

    Broad global trends suggest that economic inequality, at its historic peak according to some metrics (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2014; Piketty & Saez, 2014), is a pressing societal problem impacting the health and well-being of individuals: In roughly 70% of studies examining the health impacts of economic inequality, data indicate that societal health worsens as ...

  6. Economic Inequality

    Distribution of income across richer and poorer groups (before tax) WID, area. Income inequality: Gini coefficient before and after tax World Bank (via UN SDG) Income share of the richest 1% (before tax) WID. Income share of the richest 10% (before tax) WID. Threshold income or consumption for each decile World Bank.

  7. 6 facts about economic inequality in the U.S.

    The black-white income gap in the U.S. has persisted over time. The difference in median household incomes between white and black Americans has grown from about $23,800 in 1970 to roughly $33,000 in 2018 (as measured in 2018 dollars). Median black household income was 61% of median white household income in 2018, up modestly from 56% in 1970 ...

  8. The history of global economic inequality

    The previous and the following visualization show how high global income inequality is. The cut-off to the richest 10% of the world in 2013 was 14,500 int-$; the cut-off for the poorest 10% was 480 int-$. The ratio is 30.2. While global inequality is still very high, we live in a period of falling inequality.

  9. Consequences of Economic Inequality for the Social and Political

    Economic inequality has been found to have pernicious effects, reducing mental and physical health, decreasing societal cohesion, and fueling support for nativist parties and illiberal autocratic leaders. We start this review with an outline of what social identity theorizing offers to the study of inequality.

  10. Fighting Poverty and Inequalities Through Social Impact ...

    This chapter focuses on critical case studies involving SIBs—launched to address poverty (also in advanced economies) and socio-economic inequality issues—with the aims of understanding (1) the links and gaps between the contests and the structures of different SIB models and the ways to achieve their goals and (2) the key elements for scaling up these practices.

  11. Equality and Inequality: Articles, Research, & Case Studies

    by Avery Forman. KKR turned around a struggling door company and sold it for 10 times its investment—giving factory workers a life-changing cut of the returns. A case study by Ethan Rouen and Dennis Campbell offers lessons for companies trying to instill an owner's mindset in employees. 27 Apr 2023.

  12. Global income inequality: How big is gap between richest and poorest

    On average, an individual from the top 10% will earn $122,100, but an individual from the bottom half will earn just $3,920. And, when it comes to wealth (valuable assets and items over and above income), the gap is even wider. The poorest half of the global population owns just 2% of the global total, while the richest 10% own 76% of all wealth.

  13. Poverty Reduction: Concept, Approaches, and Case Studies

    1. Eradication of extreme poverty currently measured as people living on less than $1.25 a day for everyone everywhere by the year 2030. 2. Reduction by at least half the proportion of men, women, and children of all ages living in poverty in all its dimensions according to national definitions by the year 2030. 3.

  14. PDF Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality: SDN/15/13 A Global ...

    most existing studies have focused on advanced countries and looked at the drivers of the Gini coefficient and the income of the rich, this study explores a more diverse group of countries and pays particular attention to the income shares of the poor and the middle class—the main engines of growth. Our analysis suggests that

  15. A New Approach to Measuring Income Inequality

    In a 2020 RAND Corporation study, RAND researchers developed a new method to measure income inequality.They found that, had income for workers below the top 10 percent of the income distribution grown at the same rate as the overall economy since 1975, workers in that group would have collectively earned $2.5 trillion more in 2018, 67 percent higher than their 2018 earnings.

  16. The costs of inequality: Education's the one key that rules them all

    Third in a series on what Harvard scholars are doing to identify and understand inequality, in seeking solutions to one of America's most vexing problems.. Before Deval Patrick '78, J.D. '82, was the popular and successful two-term governor of Massachusetts, before he was managing director of high-flying Bain Capital, and long before he was Harvard's most recent Commencement speaker ...

  17. Income and Income Inequality Are a Matter of Life and Death. What Can

    For example, one study found that increasing one's annual income from $14 000 to $20 000 (a $6000 increase) would have the same benefit in life expectancy as increasing one's annual income from $161 000 to $224 000 (a $63 000 increase). 19 In another study, individuals with annual household incomes below $49 100 (in 2019 dollars) had the ...

  18. Tracking the impact of COVID-19 on economic inequality at high ...

    We study the effect of COVID-19 on inequality using bank account data from CaixaBank, the second largest Spanish bank. Caixabank had monthly records on more than 3 million wage earners in 2020, and accounted for 27.1% of the wages, salaries and benefits deposited monthly in the Spanish financial sector.

  19. "Now, What Exactly is the Problem?" Media Coverage of Economic

    Abstract: A clear sign of the heightened interest in economic inequality was the surprising popularity of Thomas Piketty's book, Capital in the Twenty‐First Century, presenting a dense synopsis and major contribution to the economics of inequality.This article investigates discourses on inequality in news media, through the highly controversial debate raised by Piketty's best‐selling book ...

  20. PDF a. Economic Change and Social Inequality: Case Study Detroit USA

    • Social Exclusion and Inequality Issues About 36 percent of the city's population is below the poverty level, and, by 2010, the residential vacancy rate was 27.8 percent. According to the U.S. Department of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics, of the 50 largest cities in the country, Detroit has the highest unemployment rate, at 23.1%.

  21. What has economics got to do with it? The impact of ...

    A clear link exists between social and economic inequality and poor mental health. There is a social gradient in mental health, and higher levels of income inequality are linked to higher ...

  22. Is Economic Inequality Really a Problem? A Review of the Arguments

    Increasing economic inequality in recent years has triggered an outpouring of analysis and reflection on the causes and consequences of these changes. Several commentators have argued that inequality does not merit all the attention it has been receiving noting that the focus on inequality can divert attention from the real problem, which is poverty. This article reviews the arguments for and ...

  23. Literature review on income inequality and economic growth

    Some studies reported no relationship between income inequality and economic growth. For example, research by Niyimbanira [44] focused on how economic growth affected income inequality from 1996-2014. That study employed the FE method and the pooled regression model, using data from 18 municipalities across the provinces of South Africa.